This text has been translated by a machine and has not been reviewed by a human yet. Apologies for any errors or approximations – do not hesitate to send us a message if you spot some!
The very sharp price rises on the wholesale electricity market in 2021, after ten years of relative stability, raise fundamental questions about their underlying causes. It is therefore necessary to take a step back from the functioning of the electricity market and the mechanisms put in place around it.
In 1996, European directives required all member countries to set up an electricity market. 1 as with other public utilities (railways, postal services, telecoms). In all countries, electricity has been partially privatized. In France, EDF’s public monopoly has had to make way for competitors, notably with the stated aim of lowering the prices paid by consumers.
In the 20 years since its inception, the market has undergone constant transformation to overcome the many difficulties it has faced. But is the market “fixable” in a sector with very specific technical characteristics? Does it accelerate the energy transition or, on the contrary, hinder it?
To shed light on these issues, we present a description and analysis of the functioning of the electricity system and the electricity market, focusing on the French case. Our aim is not to advocate a return to the pre-competitive situation, but to understand how the liberalization of the electricity market has manifested itself and what its consequences are. This is necessary in a context where current market malfunctions will lead to new European negotiations under the leadership of the Commission.
The electricity system: characteristics ill-suited to competition
Ecological constraints, strategic and societal choices
One of the special features of the electricity system is the essential nature of the commodity it supplies, for both households and businesses: our society is totally dependent on energy.
Although electricity accounts for only a quarter of final energy demand, it is irreplaceable for certain uses. And this share is set to grow in the future. This is a necessity if we are to meet our climate commitments (carbon neutrality by 2050, which implies maximum use of low-carbon electricity) and for obvious geopolitical reasons.
France had opted to guarantee all its citizens fair access to this essential commodity through a single tariff grid. The aim was to avoid penalizing rural areas far from the network, in the interests of regional planning (known as “péréquation tarifaire”). 2 .
In addition, electricity generation generates major, protean ecological impacts that vary from plant to plant: greenhouse gas emissions and air pollution (for fossil-fired power plants), impact on biodiversity and landscapes, waste production, risk of major accidents, consumption of natural and agricultural areas, etc. The choice of production methods and our energy consumption patterns are also central to strategies for achieving carbon neutrality in the face of the climate emergency. The choice of production methods and energy consumption patterns is also at the heart of strategies to achieve carbon neutrality in the face of the climate emergency.
The power system is also subject to political choices relating to energy independence: to what extent do we accept dependence on imports, whether of fuels, other elements required for production (solar panels, batteries, equipment used in power plant construction) or electricity produced by other European countries interconnected to the French grid to meet our demand? And above all, is it acceptable to entrust the means of production to large private groups, whether French or foreign (bearing in mind that business law cannot guarantee that a French player will retain control of a private company)?
The electrical system is cooperative by nature
The power system is made up of a set of generation plants with complementary characteristics, as well as networks. 3 networks, which automatically deliver electricity to consumers in real time.
At any given moment, the total production injected into the network by the various power plants must be exactly equal to the sum of consumption drawn by users from this network. In the event of even the slightest imbalance (due to the failure of a power plant or line, or to an error in forecasting consumption or production), and without prompt action by the network operator 4 the whole of Europe can be plunged into darkness in a matter of seconds.
Each consumer therefore depends on the smooth operation of the entire European power system, and not just on the resources of his or her supplier. Each component of the system must cooperate closely with the others to maintain the overall balance, despite strong uncertainties (particularly meteorological) and the multiple constraints weighing on each power plant. Each one interacts in a complementary way, in consultation with the grid operators, and certainly not in competition.
Necessary planning
Ensuring this balance requires planning on all time scales.
In the long term, planning helps determine the investments required for production and network sizing.
The government’s adoption of long-term climate and energy objectives further reinforces the need for long-term planning to define a trajectory towards totally carbon-free power generation.
These are :
- guarantee that installed generation capacity will be able to meet forecast consumption, at all times and for all conceivable operating contingencies (weather conditions, failure of one or more power plants, etc.);
- size the network capable of carrying this energy, taking into account the location of production and consumption, and any damage that may also affect the network (lightning strike, tree falling on a line, etc.).
Within these technical constraints, several investment scenarios can be envisaged, and are subject to political arbitration based on economic criteria, as well as ecological, strategic and societal ones: acceptability of a given sector, independence of supply, environmental impact, etc.
Several energy scenarios (including or excluding non-electric energies) are drawn up to inform decisions on the investments required. At power system level, they provide a variety of technically possible futures.
The most important choice when it comes to energy lies in choosing one or other of these scenarios, not in choosing an electricity supplier or a more or less green offer (see section 4.C).
The organization of in-depth public debates on these scenarios is imperative in a context of international and local tensions. No energy source is without its drawbacks. Limiting energy consumption is generally costly and difficult, especially for the most disadvantaged who have the least access to alternatives. Our fellow citizens need to understand the ins and outs of major decisions, which commit France for decades to come and can create local nuisances.
Energy planning and forecasting in France
The National Low-Carbon Strategy (SNBC ) is France’s climate policy roadmap. It is the result of regularly updated foresight work. The latest version was published in April 2020, and recognized as legally binding by a Conseil d’Etat ruling in November.
Ademe has published energy transition scenarios for 2050, covering all energies and their uses, and assessing their environmental impacts (greenhouse gas emissions, material footprint, etc.). 5 ). Part of the work is regionalized. The results are expressed in the form of four scenarios: S1 “Frugal generation”, S2 “Territorial cooperation”, S3 “Green technologies” and S4 “Restorative bet”. This work is intended in particular to feed into the next version of the SNBC, due for publication in 2023.
RTE 6 has published several electricity scenarios for the year 2050, based on a number of generation mix assumptions designed to supply different levels of consumption. 7 . The SNBC is an input to these scenarios, which require hour-by-hour simulations of production and consumption over a range of long-term climatic assumptions. They are analyzed from economic (system costs), ecological (impacts on resources, waste, carbon footprint, air and water quality, land use, etc.), sociological (implications for lifestyles, acceptability) and technical (industrial risks, etc.) angles. They take into account current and potential interconnections with neighboring countries, and integrate the potential impact of climate change on electricity production, transmission and consumption.
The NegaWatt association has carried out an all-energy forecasting exercise, which also provides the carbon and material footprints induced by the options selected. The particularity of this exercise is that it is framed by the need to phase out nuclear power as quickly as possible, and to aim for the lowest possible energy consumption.
Source Learn more: Lessons from recent energy foresight studies, Chroniques de l’Anthropocène blog (2022)
In the medium and short term, the aim is to adjust electricity production and demand.
- In the medium term, planning is essential to coordinate the maintenance periods of the various production resources. 8 and to define strategies for using the water stored in hydroelectric dams 9 .
- In the short term, and right up to real time, the aim is to coordinate generation resources and the grid in such a way as to ensure a balance between electricity demand and generation at the lowest economic cost, taking into account the various technical and environmental constraints. 10 .
This planning on all timescales aims to make the best possible use of the complementarity of each power plant, in coordination with the grid, to guarantee the balance of the power system at all times, at the lowest economic, ecological and social “cost”.
RTE is responsible for 6 to guarantee the supply-demand balance at all times, with the support of the various producers.
On the other hand, it’s up to the State to decide on the trajectories, the means of production to be installed or renovated, and to put in place the regulations and systems that will enable this to happen in the long term.
Fixed, long-term costs
The power system, both the grid and the generating fleet, is essentially made up of fixed, long-term costs: these are the characteristics of a natural monopoly. 11 .
Production costs: fixed and variable costs
Fixed production costs, which are independent of the quantity of electricity produced, include the initial investment, part of the operating costs associated with maintenance, and end-of-life investments (decommissioning). These costs also include the cost of financing investments, i.e. the return required by investors and the repayment of interest on loans.
Variable production costs, which depend on the quantities of electricity produced: these are mainly fuels (coal, gas, uranium), but also waste treatment costs and the portion of operating expenses that increases with the quantities produced.
Full cost is the sum of fixed and variable costs.
All these costs can be calculated over the entire lifetime of the plant, based on one year (fixed costs are then “annualized”) or based on the Megawatt-hour produced (the full cost is then referred to as LCOE, or Levelized Cost of Energy).
There is a consensus that electricity transmission and distribution networks are natural monopolies.
Given their costs and environmental impact, it would be absurd to develop competing networks to supply a region, a town or a district. These networks are therefore entrusted to monopoly players. In France, RTE is in charge of the transmission network, while Enedis manages the distribution network for 95% of the country (around 150 local distribution companies). 12 for the remaining 5%).
Energy market promoters, on the other hand, do not recognize this characteristic for the generating fleet.
The “market launch” of the electricity system didn’t concern the networks, but the producers and suppliers of electricity. And history has shown that, in reality, it has only concerned a small link in the value chain, namely electricity supply (see part 4 and our fact sheeton the retail electricity market ). In the generation sector, the entry of new players has been extremely limited.
This was rather inevitable, as production costs in the nuclear sector are more than 80% fixed, and this proportion approaches 100% for renewable energies (hydro, wind and photovoltaic). These costs are largely linked to the construction of the facilities, which have very long lifespans: around 30 years for solar, wind or thermal energy, 40 to 60 years for nuclear power, and sometimes well over a century for hydroelectric power.
Finally, investment in the power system is very high. They have been in the past (around €13bn/year).
This will be even more the case in the future, in order to maintain and renew an ageing fleet of power plants, and to maintain and adapt networks to support the energy transition (around €20 to €25 billion/year). According to RTE, investments in generation account for around two-thirds of the total amount invested. 13 .
Under these conditions, for both generation facilities and grids, it is of course undesirable to build more generation facilities than necessary, simply to put them in competition with each other and keep only the “best”, i.e. those that produce at the lowest cost. All the more so since, like networks, they have a major impact on the environment, and the possible sites are limited by physical constraints and the acceptability of the structures. Nor, of course, is it desirable to under-invest, which could happen if the market price is insufficiently remunerative or too volatile.
Electricity is an undifferentiated product, and demand is not very adaptable to supply.
Once the generating facilities are built, the electricity delivered is the same for everyone
An electron remains an electron, and it’s not possible to guarantee consumers where their electricity comes from. 14 . The choice of type of generation (e.g. nuclear or 100% renewable) is made at the time the power plants are built. Some players see this as a way of differentiating the “electricity product”, through green offers that are supposed to guarantee 100% renewable origin, or more precisely, as an incentive to build renewable production facilities. As we’ll see in section 4.C, however, this is a false promise.
Nor can offers be differentiated on the basis of the quality of the electricity delivered (greater or lesser frequency of power cuts or voltage drops), since this depends on the network. 15 and the generation facilities connected to it, not the electricity supplier.
For more details on this point, you can also consult our fact sheet explaining just how little differentiation there is between electricity supply offers.
Electricity demand is not very price-elastic
Furthermore, the existence of a market depends on the ability of both supply and demand to adapt to each other: in theory, demand should fall when prices are high, and rise when prices are low.
Yet electricity demand is extremely constrained: for a household, it is difficult to significantly reduce or shift electricity consumption without worsening living conditions; for a company, a drop in electricity consumption would lead to a halt or shift in production, resulting in technical and/or economic difficulties. 16 . Conversely, consumers are not going to suddenly start consuming on a massive scale because prices are low.
Electricity demand is not very price-elastic: in the short term, a rise (or fall) in price does not translate into a significant fall (or rise) in consumption. In fact, consumption is largely determined by structural factors (hours of consumption depending on organizational constraints, better or worse insulation of homes, more or less efficient electrical and electronic appliances, production processes, etc.) which can only be changed over the long term, via investment in particular.
There are also solutions for adapting demand to production at the level of the power system itself. However, uses that can be shifted in time or “erased 17 are currently limited (certain industrial uses, and, for residential customers, the activation of hot water tanks, washing machines and dishwashers), and electricity can only be stored to a very limited extent: today, essentially in the form of water in dams, tomorrow possibly in the form of hydrogen or biomethane, and through the use of batteries, with the possible contribution of batteries for electric vehicles, which are set to expand rapidly. This is a real challenge, but it requires technological leaps, major investments and an organization of the power system that enables these levers to be effectively managed.
How did the opening up to competition come about?
Because of the specific features of the electricity system, a public monopoly (EDF-GDF) was set up after the war to manage electricity and gas in France. In other countries, various organizations were set up 18 most of them public, but with varying degrees of centralization depending on the country’s history, culture, organization, geography and available energy resources (coal in Germany, coal and gas in the UK, hydroelectricity in France, etc.). 19 . Exchanges between interconnected European countries were organized between national grid operators.
Since 1996, the electricity (and gas) sectors have been gradually opened up to competition. As we shall see, despite major changes in the way the system is organized, this competition remains fairly artificial. What’s more, it is driving up the system’s overall costs.
Opening up to competition has led to a profound transformation of the electricity system
In 1996, a European directive required all EU member states to set up an electricity market, considered to be :
particularly important for rationalizing the production, transmission and distribution of electricity, while strengthening the security of supply and competitiveness of the European economy and respecting environmental protection.
Competition is justified in particular by the objective of low prices.
If, in the face of market failure, some economists 20 now dispute this initial statement, European texts are clear on this point. For example, the first sentence of the European Commission’s website dedicated to the electricity market states: “An integrated European energy market is the most economically efficient way to ensure a secure and affordable energy supply for European citizens”.
The President of the European Commission, Romano Prodi, at the Barcelona European Council of March 15 and 16 2002, which marked an acceleration in the liberalization of the gas and electricity markets, also made this promise clear: “It is clear that this agreement will lead to a reduction in prices and an increase in competition”. 21 . He even went so far as to put a figure on the savings expected from these price cuts: “Full liberalization would result in annual savings of 15 billion euros in lower prices”. 22 .
As elsewhere in Europe, the organization of the French electricity sector has undergone a profound transformation.
- EDF and GDF were separated into two separate companies (one for electricity, the other for gas) and became private companies, in order to avoid benefiting from a public guarantee ensuring better financing conditions than their competitors.
- Network management, recognized from the outset as a natural monopoly, has been separated from the supposedly “competitive” generation and supply activities. Today, it is carried out by two EDF subsidiaries that must guarantee their independence from the parent company: RTE for the high-voltage network, and Enedis for the medium- and low-voltage networks. 23 .
- New players – producers but above all suppliers – have emerged, and markets have been set up to organize exchanges between them.
- An independent administrative authority, the Commission de Régulation de l’Energie (CRE), has been set up to ensure the smooth operation of the electricity and gas markets.
The electricity market has developed on two levels.
- The wholesale market, which organizes electricity trading between industry professionals (producers, suppliers and large industrial customers) via an exchange(see Part 3).
- The retail market, which represents all contracts between suppliers and end consumers (households, businesses, public authorities, etc.): commercial offers (known as market offers) and the regulated sales tariff offered by incumbent suppliers (EDF and local distribution companies, etc.). 12 )(see section 4). This is not a stock exchange.
Off-market competition for power generation
Once selected, producers are no longer in competition with each other.
To encourage the emergence of new producers, in the early years of the opening up of the electricity markets, the management of certain public production facilities was transferred to private players. Thus, part of the management of hydroelectric production on the Rhône was transferred to the Compagnie Nationale du Rhône (CNR), now a subsidiary of Engie. 24 .
Other means of production were developed by private investors. First there were combined-cycle gas turbine (CCGT) power plants, which were supposed to be paid for on the market, but for which support mechanisms had to be put in place. Then came privately financed wind and solar power plants. However, as we’ll see in part 3, wholesale market prices are highly volatile and far too uncertain for producers to take the risk of investing for the long term on the basis of this market alone.
That’s why these new production capacities have been financed via non-market mechanisms, in the form of feed-in tariffs guaranteed for the entire life of the facilities, or remuneration supplements(see Appendix 1).
Investors thus benefit from a long-term contract with the State. Their situation is comparable to that of freeway, airport or water distribution operators.
The challenge of financing low-carbon energies
The cost of low-carbon energies is characterized by the high proportion of investment depreciation (CAPEX) and capital costs compared with operating costs (OPEX).
Indeed, the cost of fuel, which represents a significant proportion of operating costs, is zero for hydroelectric, photovoltaic and wind power plants, and low for nuclear power plants.
The cost of capital is a determining factor in the overall cost of electricity, as noted by David Newberry, one of the economists who theorized about deregulation of the sector in the UK: “All low-carbon technologies have costs that are extremely sensitive to their cost of capital”. 25 (see box).
The cost of investment financing: a key parameter
Given the predominance of fixed costs (and therefore investment), the total cost of the power system is highly sensitive to the cost of financing.
RTE’s “Energy Futures 2050” study highlights the importance of this parameter right at the start of the economic chapter: “For a variation in the annual rate of return on capital ranging from 1% to 7%, the full annual cost varies by more than €35 bn/year for all scenarios, an order of magnitude far greater than the differences due to the respective proportions of renewable and nuclear generation”.

Source : Futurs énergétiques 2050(chapter 11, fig.11.36), RTE
As shown in the graph above, the full annualized cost of the 100% renewable scenario (M23) is €55 bn per year for a financing rate (or CPMC _ weighted average cost of capital) of 1%, a rate that the French government can easily afford today. This rises to €90 bn/year for a rate of 7%, which is the typical rate demanded by private investors. This represents a 64% increase in the total cost!
The impact is of the same order for the reference scenario with nuclear power (N2), whose cost rises from €42 to €91 billion (+82%) when the financing rate (CPMC) is increased from 1% to 7%.
What’s more, when renewable energies were launched, they were still immature and required subsidies for their development. The free functioning of the market could not help them to emerge. 26 . Similar questions about financing arise today for nuclear power (with the new EPRs), as well as for new hydroelectric facilities whose cost price may be higher than the market price of electricity.
The French government has therefore put in place non-market instruments to enable the deployment of renewable energies. Feed-in tariffs for wind and solar power guaranteed developers long-term returns. At the same time, a global dynamic led to considerable reductions in the cost of renewables. As a result, we have seen significant over-remuneration, as noted by the Cour des Comptes in a report on support for renewable energies in April 2018. These initial feed-in tariffs still weigh in part on consumers’ bills, despite substantial modifications to the arrangements (see Appendix 1).
It should be noted here that the cost of capital theoretically serves to remunerate the “present preference” and risk-taking of the financier. However, we need to distinguish between two types of risk: the commercial risk (of unsold power or of selling at too low a price in relation to costs)-which can be eliminated with guaranteed tariffs and/or additional remuneration-and the industrial risk (of construction, risk of cost overruns or excessive delays), which is particularly sensitive in the case of nuclear power.
Growing industrial expertise and price guarantee mechanisms have enabled renewable energy developers to reduce the cost of capital. Until 2020, renewable energy projects were still being financed with a Weighted Average Cost of Capital of less than 27 than 5% (with 3/4 borrowed at ~3% and the remaining 1/4 financed by equity at ~10%). This, of course, still weighs on the cost of the electricity produced, especially as the initial capital is remunerated over the entire operating life of the project, not just the construction period.
It should also be noted that the new EPRs, in view of the cost and schedule drift observed for the first ones (Olkiluoto and Flamanville, but also to a lesser extent Hinkley-Point), appear to be industrially risky. For a private player, financing them would require a higher, even prohibitive, cost of capital, unless a state guarantee were to be put in place.
To conclude on this point, it is clear that the construction of low-carbon power plants cannot be achieved by relying on market mechanisms alone.
Should competition apply to plant construction and operation?
Apart from existing nuclear and hydroelectric power plants, developers of power plant projects are not necessarily the operators. Nor are they necessarily the builders.
In the nuclear sector, while the current fleet was built and is operated by EDF, the technology was put out to tender: Westinghouse won out over General Electric and CEA.
This means that competition in generation technologies, plant construction and maintenance services does not mean that the operation of these plants has to be managed by competing players, nor, above all, that investments have to be remunerated over the entire lifetime of the plant.
Inviting tenders not only for the construction of the park, but also for its operation, is likely to lead to a number of problems:
- This significantly increases the cost of production: the investor who responds to the call for tenders will not be reimbursed on delivery of the plant (at the end of the construction phase), but progressively over its entire operating life, via guaranteed tariffs or similar mechanisms. It therefore acts as a lender to the community over a very long period, and is remunerated at a higher rate than a public loan.
- For controllable controllers 28 management by a single operator allows better optimization of the call program.
- Strategically, and for reasons of democratic control, it seems preferable not to depend on the decisions of private French or foreign players for production as sensitive as that of electricity. 29
In addition, competition in the upstream construction phase of a wind farm does not obviate the need to consider the national and European strategy that needs to be put in place to manage these activities (wind power, photovoltaics, storage, etc.). 30 (see section 5). This can be achieved through the development of industry sectors, under the impetus of the government, which is in a position to organize these sectors (in particular through research, training, skills development, etc.).
The electricity supply business was created for the purposes of competition.
Financial and commercial activity, marginal and useless
Before the market was opened up, EDF billed all French consumers for the electricity it generated, transmitted and distributed (except for the 5% of the territory served by local distribution companies). 12 .
Today, in addition to the incumbent suppliers (EDF and ELD), the French retail market includes some 80 so-called “alternative” suppliers (40 of which are for residential consumers).
These include foreign electricity companies (Vattenfall, Iberdrola, etc.), oil companies (ENI, Total Energie), gas companies (Engie, formerly GDF), start-ups, retail chains (Carrefour, Cdiscount, etc.) and militant cooperatives (Enercoop). 31 . These alternative suppliers bill electricity to around 12 million sites (including 10 million residential sites).
As the following chart shows, alternative suppliers account for 43% of the total volume of electricity sold in France, with a stronger presence in the very large customer segment (electro-intensive businesses) and a weaker presence in the residential sector.
Market share of EDF and alternative suppliers by type of offer and type of consumer

Source Observatoire des marchés de détail du 2e trimestre 2021 – Commission de régulation de l’énergie (CRE)
Suppliers buy electricity from producers and sell it to consumers. They are not involved in the technical side of the business, nor do they “touch” electricity production. 32 or its transmission to the consumer. As we have seen, electricity is transmitted automatically, with no possibility for suppliers to intervene: in particular, they cannot choose which generation plants will supply their customers. Nor do they store electricity or read meters (this is done by network operators).
Suppliers are limited to acting as financial and commercial intermediaries between producers and end consumers. They draw up sales offers, canvass customers, buy on the wholesale electricity markets, and issue invoices to their customers (generating re-invoicing by network operators for the part of the invoice linked to network use).
Supply activity adds cost and complexity to the power system
Before the opening to competition, there was no trading, canvassing or marketing, since the monopoly producer EDF sold electricity directly to all users, according to a single, simple price scale, set to cover the overall production costs of the electricity system(see section 4).
Many of the activities carried out by suppliers therefore result in additional costs for the power system: creation of commercial and trading functions (to buy electricity on the wholesale market), duplication of support functions (billing, administration, consumption forecasting, etc.) at each supplier, transaction costs linked to the contractualization of exchanges, and so on. These additional costs are, of course, passed on to the end consumer.
On the other hand, the customer relations provided by the public service in the past have deteriorated (whatever the type of consumer, but particularly for the most vulnerable): agencies providing a physical welcome have disappeared; neutral information has given way to particularly aggressive marketing and commercial canvassing, regularly denounced by the Energy Ombudsman and consumer associations. 33 Consumers are tossed back and forth between Enedis, for network-related problems, and EDF or another supplier for contractual issues. Precarious customers receive less support and are less aware of the assistance available to them. For industrial customers, professions that used to involve highly specialized knowledge of electricity-intensive uses (e.g. arc furnaces) are tending to disappear(see section 5).
The wholesale market poses many problems
The emergence of new players (producers and suppliers) necessitated the creation of an exchange: the wholesale electricity market, which defines an exchange price between these players.
The wholesale market is also supposed to ensure coordination between these players to guarantee the balance of the power system from the short term (making the right operational management decisions) to the long term (making the right investment decisions over several decades), even though markets only exist over a three-year horizon.
Highly volatile wholesale prices
Electricity generation facilities are called up according to the merit order principle (which pre-existed the market).
At any given moment, we need to define the production plan for all power plants, known as the call schedule: this is the quantity of electricity to be produced by each power plant to meet electricity demand at the lowest cost, on the entire interconnected European grid.
The calling program is determined according to the economic “merit order” principle, in compliance with all technical and environmental constraints. 35 power plants are called up in ascending order of variable cost. Indeed, once investments have been made, fixed costs are no longer taken into account, since they can no longer evolve (they do not depend on operational decisions linked to the running of the generating fleet). The only possible lever for reducing system costs is therefore to minimize variable costs, which are the only ones that depend on the quantity of electricity generated.
The power plant with the lowest cost is called first, and so on: non-storable renewable generation with a variable cost of zero (photovoltaic, wind and run-of-river hydro) is therefore called first, followed by nuclear power plants and then gas and coal-fired power plants. 36 . The water in hydroelectric dams, whose cost is zero but whose quantity is limited, is assigned a fictitious value that makes it possible to decide whether it should be turbined to produce today, or stored to produce in the future. 37 .
Determining this call programme is a highly complex task. It requires a fine-tuned vision of the entire fleet, due to the many constraints weighing on the power plants, which bind them together, or which make it necessary to manage stocks (of water in dams, but also of fuel in nuclear power plants, or of demand-side shaving potential, etc.). 38 ) in an uncertain future, as they are highly dependent on climatic conditions.
Wholesale electricity prices are based on marginal cost, making them highly volatile.
The wholesale market price is equal to the cost of increasing consumption by 1 MWh at a given time: this is known as the marginal cost. This cost corresponds broadly to the variable cost of the last (i.e. highest) power plant called on the interconnected European grid, known as the marginal cost of production. As this is often a gas- or coal-fired plant, this marginal cost depends largely on the cost of the gas or coal fuel. 39 the main variable cost component for these plants. 40
This is why, although the price of gas accounts for only a small proportion of the total cost of electricity generation (around 7% in France or Germany), its wholesale price is mostly dependent on it, making it highly volatile and difficult for the public authorities to control.
Definitions
Wholesale prices are the prices governing exchanges between professionals on the wholesale market. They cover different types of prices (intraday, spot and forward), depending on the time between purchase and delivery of the electricity.
Spot price: refers to the price of electricity purchased for next-day delivery.
Forward price: refers to the price of electricity purchased for delivery over a longer period, between 1 month and 3 years after purchase. The most common forward price, and the one most widely used as an index to establish the selling price to consumers, is the purchase price for calendar delivery (the whole year) following the purchase (called Year Ahead).
Spot prices can fluctuate from 0 to several hundred or even thousands of euros per MWh, depending on delivery times.
Spot price trend in a “normal” winter month (December 2018)

Source EPEX
Reading: during December 2018, the price of a MWh quoted the previous day varied between around €0 and €90/MWh depending on the time of delivery.
The forward price represents the purchase of 1 MWh for future delivery, over a timeframe ranging from one month to several years. This price is likely to be very stable, since it is not impacted, a priori, by cyclical hazards (weather or power failures) and average annual electricity demand changes little (except for the particular period of 2020 linked to Covid).
However, this price is also highly volatile, albeit to a lesser extent, as shown in the graph below.
Forward prices have varied between around €20 and €170/MWh over the period presented (2002-Oct 2021). They even exceeded €250/MWh in December 2021.
At the same time, production costs have changed very little (see graph below on the breakdown of power system costs).
Year-ahead prices in France from 2002 to 2021

Source EPEX
Reading: on January 1, 2016, the purchase of 1 MWh for each hour of 2017 was priced at around €26/MWh. On October 3, 2021 (for delivery in 2022), it was €170/MWh.
Volatility is highly correlated with that of fossil fuels. The graph above shows the effect of rising commodity prices (fuel and CO2 prices) up to 2006; then the bursting of the European CO2 bubble, causing prices to plummet; then the surge in fuel prices in 2008, largely linked to the Beijing Olympics (causing tension on freight); then the collapse due to the 2008 financial crisis; then a further rise in commodity prices from 2009 to 2012; then the fall in prices induced by the discovery of American shale gas until 2016. ; followed by a further rise in coal and gas prices, until the recent gas crisis at the end of 2021, linked to the post-Covid global recovery and problems with Russian gas supplies to Europe.
Breakdown and evolution of French power system costs (generation and grids) 2012-2021

Source Author’s calculations based on AIE, SER, EDF, RTE, CRE, Observ’ER, EPEX/EEX. Download the excel file used to make the calculations.
In the long term, the market provides neither the visibility nor the returns required for investment.
As electricity production costs are largely made up of heavy investments amortized over several decades and fixed operating costs, it is imperative for the investor to have visibility on revenues throughout the amortization period.
In practice, investments in the electricity system are planned outside the market.
First of all, it’s important to remember that energy choices not only have an economic dimension, but also other criteria that are at least as important: ecological, geopolitical, industrial, societal and so on.
Investments are therefore the result of planned political decisions, based on long-term scenarios that guarantee the balance of the power system(see section 1). They are not market-driven, any more than they were in the past. 41 . For example, hydroelectric plants were built to the maximum available capacity; nuclear power plants were developed primarily in the name of France’s energy independence. 42 and wind and solar power are designed to diversify non-carbon sources alongside or in place of nuclear power.
The market is not able to take into account the diversity of these criteria, especially as it does not provide any visibility beyond 3 years, the maximum timeframe for quoting futures products on the existing wholesale market. 43 .
The market price is insufficient to finance the investment
At first glance, it may seem incomprehensible to have thought that the market price, based on marginal cost, would be capable of remunerating each plant at its fair value, i.e. covering both its fixed and variable costs (including a reasonable margin). This is a prerequisite if the market price is to provide the right incentive for investment, and tend towards an economically optimized system.
This property stems from an economic theory 44 which postulates that, under certain conditions, marginal costs are indeed equal, on average, to the full costs of each means of production. For example, over an average year, when nuclear power plants are in operation, they are remunerated at a marginal cost that is most often equal to the variable cost of gas-fired power plants. This enables them to remunerate not only the variable costs of nuclear power, which are much lower than those of gas-fired plants, but also – thanks to the difference between the marginal cost and the variable cost of nuclear power – the variable costs of gas-fired plants. 45 fixed costs (including depreciation and investment financing).
Unfortunately, this theory is very fragile, since it assumes that system costs, which are essentially fixed and long-term, will be covered by remuneration based exclusively on the variable cost of peak generation. Above all, the assumptions on which they are based are inapplicable in a market environment, whatever the composition of the generating fleet (see Appendix 3). Finally, wholesale prices are disconnected from power system costs, and unable to guarantee generators a return on their investment. For example, in the early 2010s, several producers invested in gas-fired power plants in Germany; a few years later, as a result of falling market prices and the inversion of costs between gas- and coal-fired generation (the latter once again becoming the cheapest), they were forced to “mothball” these brand-new plants, i.e. shut them down to at least avoid fixed operating costs.
The failure of the market to guide investment is now widely recognized 46 . This is why, over the years, various market bypass mechanisms have been put in place to provide visibility and guarantees for producers: guaranteed feed-in tariffs or contracts for difference, long-term contracts, complementary markets, etc. These are just a few examples. 47 (see Appendix 1).
The European Commission constantly criticizes these mechanisms as distortions of the free play of competition, but is forced to come to terms with them every time, given the extent of the market’s malfunctioning. Moreover, these mechanisms for circumventing the market are not exclusive to France: even the very liberal United Kingdom, for example, has introduced long-term contracts in all production sectors.
Some economists see the wholesale market’s inability to finance investment as a consequence of the development of intermittent renewable energies – solar and wind – whose zero variable cost is particularly at odds with theory. In reality, this major dysfunction concerns all production sectors. No new power plant can be built if the investor has to be remunerated by a market price that is highly volatile and disconnected from the full costs of production (mainly made up of fixed costs). The same applies to the capital-intensive balancing facilities required for the energy transition, such as hydroelectric pumping stations (STEP) and electrolysers for hydrogen production (see Appendix 1).
In the short term, the market is less efficient than an integrated system
While there is a consensus that the market fails to promote the right investment decisions, many economists continue to attribute to it the ability to effectively coordinate the various means of production, in order to define at any given moment the optimal production program, i.e. at the lowest operating cost. The market thus retains its role as short-term coordinator.
First of all, it should be noted that in a system where fixed costs account for almost 80% of the total, short-term coordination represents a limited, if not negligible, challenge. Above all, both theory and practice show that market coordination is less effective than coordination by a single operator.
Market coordination less economically efficient than a single player
As we saw in section 3.A, whatever the organization of the power system, plant production plans (call schedules) are defined according to an economic merit order, in ascending order of variable cost.
Prior to deregulation, EDF carried out this short-term coordination by merit order, using optimization programs that took into account the many constraints and hazards affecting the generating fleet in order to determine the optimum call schedule.
In a system where there is no longer a single operator, but rather a group of producers and buyers (suppliers), each player has only part of the information at their disposal, and coordinates via the market. The general optimization problem previously solved by the single operator therefore undergoes a “price decomposition”, so that each actor is assigned a sub-problem. However, due to the nature of the constraints 48 on the generating fleet, this multiplication of players systematically degrades the calling program and drives up costs, even in an ideal situation where the market price would be “perfect” and all players would play a fully virtuous game for the community, i.e. seek to minimize the full cost of electricity (which is far from being the case in reality, see next point).
This result is widely documented in the scientific literature 49 but is also supported by practical experience: players with large fleets don’t determine the call schedule for their fleets by simply simulating a market 50 .
In short, centralized optimization by an efficient, integrated player delivers better results than a perfect market, let alone the real thing.
Recourse to the market multiplies the risk of abuse of a dominant position
Some advocates of competition point to the danger of a concentration of resources in the hands of a single player who could exercise market power, i.e. manipulate prices to his own advantage and to the detriment of consumers. We note that this fear is not backed up by any concrete examples, despite the numerous case studies of electricity systems managed by public monopolies.
Analysis of numerous foreign examples 51 including the emblematic Californian disaster of 2001, shows that the multiplication of private players does not prevent them from exercising strong market power. Given the technical characteristics of the electricity system, the failure of just a few generating units is enough to jeopardize the entire network during periods of high consumption: if a player refuses to produce, there is a risk of blackout, and prices soar.
The question arises, however, in the more complex case of France’s integration into a European “plate”. This centralized optimization could not be left to EDF. We’ll come back to this point later (in the paragraph on European coordination).
The fiasco of electricity market liberalization in California (2001)
In California, liberalization was implemented in 1996: the two incumbent producers were forced to sell off their production facilities, allowing seven private producers to emerge. Companies specializing in energy trading (purchase for resale on the markets and speculation on stock market prices) sprang up, such as Enron.
The ensuing near-total halt in investment, and above all the manipulation of market prices by producers who “held back” their production on the pretext of unavailability, created artificial shortages that sent prices soaring and put distributors in difficulty.
This crisis led to 38 days of rolling blackouts in California, a 40% increase in electricity rates, a 35% reduction in the number of employees in the electrical industry, a $45 billion loss for the State of California between 2000 and 2001, and the placing of this state, the richest in the United States, under surveillance by the financial community, a treatment generally reserved for developing countries.
Finally, the Californian state had to step in for distributors threatened with bankruptcy and buy electricity at exorbitant prices under long-term contracts running until 2011. This unfortunate experience put a stop to the liberalization experiment in 23 US states.
Source The Californian experience is recounted in detail in François Soulte’s book EDF Chronique d’un désastre inéluctable (2003) and Gilles Ballastre’s documentary Les apprentis sorciers (2005), which features interviews with Californian electricity players (see a transcript of these interviews here). You can also read this twitter thread dedicated to the Californian disaster.
To prevent such manipulation, we need to keep a very close eye on the producer, as the Commission de Régulation de l’Energie is doing today with EDF. 52
We can also envisage entrusting production to a player whose primary objective is to provide a service mission, as is the case with companies with public status. EPIC (Établissement Public à Caractère Industriel et Commercial) status, for example, requires that all profits be reinvested. The company has no interest in manipulating the market.
Is national de-optimization offset by better European coordination?
Has the opening up of markets led to better coordination between countries? Has it led to lower operating costs that could more than offset the national de-optimization discussed above?
While the interconnection of the European network long predates the introduction of markets, it’s true that coordination between countries has improved over the last few decades. But is this improved intra-European complementarity attributable to the market?
Geopolitical factors, such as the fall of the Berlin Wall, and technical factors, such as the development of intermittent renewable energies, which make it increasingly necessary to pool peak load resources and the “proliferation” of consumption, may also explain this development, which began in the era of public monopolies. It should also be noted that methodological progress in the management of exchange capacities between European countries via interconnection lines is not linked to market regulation of the European power system.
The rules of the European market mean that each country accepts to lose some control over the operation of its generating fleet, in order to submit to the call program coordinated at European level by the stock market operators. It becomes impossible, for example, for a country to give priority to the operation of a national power plant for reasons of economic balance or local employment, or on the basis of ecological criteria that would contravene the merit order. 53 . In return for this loss of sovereignty, the optimized European call schedule makes the best possible use of the complementarity of generation resources and the abundance of demand between different countries, via interconnections. 54 .
However, just as at national level, the market is not the best solution for short-term European coordination. A centralized public optimizer at European level would be the best solution. 55 which would apply collectively-defined merit oder rules and have visibility over information on the different means of production, could do a better job than the market.
Optimizing the operation of generation facilities on a European scale therefore does not in itself require the creation of a market, with its attendant perverse economic, social and democratic effects.
Finally, it should be remembered that the introduction of electricity markets is only intended to ensure short-term coordination of the European fleet (i.e. its operation), and not to plan and coordinate investments. However, it is the latter that is the most important in terms of cost (see section 1.D). Coordinated investment planning on a European scale, while respecting the constraints specific to each country (e.g. choice of technology, preservation of a certain level of energy independence), would therefore have a far greater impact, and would make it possible, for example, to pool peak resources.
The retail market: the impossible equation between the need for price stability and the market
What is the retail electricity market?
As we saw in part 2, the opening up to competition has introduced new intermediaries, suppliers, whose role is to buy electricity on the wholesale market from producers and resell it to consumers. 56 .
The wholesale market refers to the exchange between electricity professionals (in particular suppliers’ purchases from producers). It’s worth noting that a large proportion of exchanges escape the market: on the one hand, because EDF, which holds around 80% of production and almost 60% of customers (in terms of volume sold), supplies its customers largely through its own production, without going through the markets; on the other hand, because alternative suppliers can access part of the nuclear electricity produced by EDF at the regulated price of €42/MWh through a market bypass mechanism, ARENH (Accès Régulé à l’Électricité Nucléaire Historique, see part 4.C).
The retail market refers to contracts between suppliers and end consumers (individuals or businesses). Unlike the wholesale market, it is not organized like a stock exchange, since it operates via bilateral contracts.
Whatever the type of contract, the electricity bill paid by consumers breaks down into three major cost items, of equivalent importance for a domestic consumer:
- TURPE (Tarif d’Utilisation des Réseaux Publics d’Électricité), a regulated tariff set by the French energy regulator, covering the cost of access to the transmission and distribution network.
- The energy share is intended to cover the costs of producing and supplying (or marketing) electricity.
- Taxes and contributions set by the public authorities (including, in particular, additional remuneration for renewable energies) 57 .
Suppliers therefore only set the price of the energy part of the bill, which is the only part “in competition”.
From theory to reality
In theory, the energy portion of electricity bills should perfectly reflect wholesale prices, in order to pass on to consumers the market’s supposedly optimal pricing incentives. This is the principle of dynamic pricing promoted by the European Commission (see appendix 2), one of whose aims is to meet the power system’s need for flexibility by encouraging consumers to shift their consumption to less peak hours.
However, to date, consumers do not have the means to significantly adapt their consumption to real-time prices, unless they jeopardize their business for companies, or go without heating and basic uses of electricity for private individuals: they can only shift a few uses, for example, hot water tanks and washing machines (to be started at night or midday rather than at the end of the day). Incentives to shift this type of use have existed for decades in the form of “off-peak” tariffs. 58 . It is entirely possible to further improve the adaptation of demand to production that is set to become more intermittent (wind and solar power), without seriously penalizing consumers or exposing them to the extreme volatility of wholesale market prices, by using “abundance”. 59 of consumption. This implies seeking the overall balance of the power system (which is what an integrated player would do), rather than individual opportunities for each supplier.
While dynamic pricing is not (yet!) the norm, we will see that liberalization of the electricity market has resulted in a shift from a system where retail prices based on production costs were relatively stable, to a system where retail prices are increasingly indexed to wholesale market prices.
The majority of consumers (individuals and businesses) find themselves exposed to market prices, whose volatility (see section 3.A) is incompatible with their need for price stability for the essential commodity of electricity.
Faced with the difficulties caused by this volatility in market prices, workaround mechanisms have been put in place to dampen fluctuations. These shock absorbers are more or less developed in different countries, which goes a long way towards explaining why the surge in gas prices in 2021, which was reflected in wholesale electricity prices in all European countries, did not have the same impact on consumer bills everywhere.
Historical operation: regulated sales tariffs (TRV)
Before the market was opened up, only the incumbent operator supplied electricity to consumers. All consumers had access to the same tariff grid: green tariffs for large consumers (industrial), yellow tariffs for medium consumers (small industries and tertiary businesses), professional blue tariffs for small businesses, and residential blue tariffs for individuals. In each category, prices depended on the level of subscribed power and options reflecting their consumption profile, offering a good compromise between price stability and incentives to consume at times most convenient for the power system. 60 .
These tariffs were calculated to cover, on average, all production costs (including fixed costs) as well as transmission and distribution costs.
Each year, tariffs were adjusted in line with electricity system costs. As these costs were not likely to change abruptly, the trend was moderate, guaranteeing a degree of stability.
In a 2019 note, INSEE states: “After this counter-shock [1986], the nominal price of electricity evolved very moderately until 2007 (+2.6% between 1986 and 2007). This relative stability can be explained first and foremost by the commissioning of numerous nuclear power plants during the 1980s: electricity production costs are disconnected from fluctuations in hydrocarbon prices.” 61
Opening up to competition and diversifying electricity supply offers
The introduction of market offers and the abolition of regulated sales tariffs for businesses
The opening up to competition has meant that consumers can “choose” their suppliers and opt for different types of contract.
Opening up the market has been a gradual process, starting in 1999 with the largest customers, followed by smaller and smaller companies until 2004. In 2007, it was opened up to domestic consumers.
For businesses, regulated sales tariffs initially coexisted with market offers. But customers who decided to leave the regulated tariffs had no right of return. Now, trapped by soaring wholesale prices that were threatening their financial health, in 2007 companies obtained from the legislator a right to return in return for a penalty of 20 to 23% of the initial tariff.
In 2007, at the instigation of alternative suppliers, the European Commission opened a State Aid procedure against France, with the aim of abolishing the TRV and return tariffs. These mechanisms are being challenged on the grounds of unfair competition, since, as Electrabel wrote: “Almost all Electrabel customer sites have asked to benefit from the return tariff. The return tariff has led to a gradual displacement of alternative suppliers in favor of EDF, since customers often prefer the latter for the same price”. 62 .
The French government reacted to this procedure by creating Regulated Access to Historic Nuclear Electricity (ARENH _ see next section) and by phasing out all regulated sales tariffs for businesses, which has been in place since 2015 (with the exception of very small businesses). Companies have therefore been forced to “choose” market offers.
Domestic customers and very small businesses continue to have access to the blue tariff, but only for a temporary period. 63 . They can choose between :
- The regulated sales tariff, set by the public authorities and still offered by the incumbent suppliers (EDF and the local distribution companies), is the only way to reduce the price of electricity. 12 ), but with major changes in the way they are calculated (see below).
- Market offers, proposed by all suppliers (alternative and incumbent) within the framework of contracts. These can be either fixed-price offers (where the price, excluding taxes, remains unchanged for the duration of the contract) or indexed-price offers (where the price follows changes in regulated sales tariffs or wholesale market indices specified in the contract).
ARENH (Regulated Access to Historic Nuclear Electricity): a non-market mechanism to stimulate competition!
In response to the state aid procedure initiated by the European Commission in 2007, France introduced a mechanism called ARENH in 2011. Due to expire in 2025, this mechanism requires EDF to make available to its competitors at a fixed price (€42/MWh corresponding to an estimate of the cost of production) around a quarter of its nuclear production (i.e. 100 TWh), corresponding to their market share in 2011.
The stated aim of ARENH is to put an end to the unfair competition that alternative suppliers would face from EDF, since the public operator benefits from the low-cost production of the historical nuclear fleet, which has been largely amortized. By giving alternative suppliers access to part of this production at cost price, ARENH would encourage competition in the supply business while competitors develop new production capacity.
How does ARENH and the capping mechanism work?
Under the ARENH scheme, EDF is obliged to sell up to 100 TWh to its competitors each year at the fixed price of €42 MWH, which is supposed to represent the production costs of the historic nuclear power plant.
In November, alternative suppliers submit their requests for ARENH volumes for the following twelve months to the Commission de régulation de l’énergie. They do so on the basis of their customers’ forecast consumption during low-consumption hours (known as “ARENH Hours”).
If overall demand exceeds the statutory ceiling of 100 TWh (as has been the case since 2019), the Commission de Régulation de l’Energie (CRE) will 64 must then proceed to capping ARENH volumes: after examining the validity of requests, it proportionally distributes the 100 TWh available. For example, during the November 2021 auction for the 2022 delivery year, the CRE received around 160 TWh of ARENH requests: after capping, each alternative supplier was allocated 62.37% of the volume requested, and will have to purchase the missing volumes directly on the wholesale market.
Source For more information, visit the EDF website or the CRE website.
ARENH is an asymmetrical mechanism.
Up to 100 TWh 65 alternative suppliers have the choice of either purchasing at cost (i.e., at the ARENH price of €42/MWh), or on the wholesale market when the latter falls below cost. The mechanism also offers them opportunities for speculation. For example, when prices were low in 2016, some alternative suppliers bought forward on the wholesale market, then resold at a higher price when prices rose in 2017, relying on ARENH to supply their customers.
Producer EDF, for its part, finds itself in a difficult situation, obliged to sell at a loss when the market price collapses (as, for example, in 2016, when it remained around €30/MWh for over a year) and to sell at cost price (at ARENH) when market prices are above €42/MWH. Of course, EDF argued that this mechanism was a drain on its finances and hampered its ability to invest.
On the consumer side, ARENH has acted as a powerful shock absorber against price rises on the wholesale market. Indeed, the regulated sales tariffs, which serve as a guide for other offers and today reflect the supply mode of alternative suppliers, include ARENH to a large extent in their calculation, reducing the proportion indexed to the wholesale market (see next section).
ARENH is the subject of much criticism from all players. Debates revolve around several points:
- The price: EDF has long been calling for an increase in the €42/MWh price, which was set in 2012 and has not been reviewed since. However, it is difficult to form an opinion on the reality of nuclear production costs, as they are so opaque.
- The asymmetrical aspect of the mechanism: rarely highlighted, this aspect is the most dangerous and penalizing for EDF (and therefore ultimately for consumers and taxpayers);
- The volume accessible to ARENH (100 TWh excluding the exceptional 2022 measure): supported by the Commission de régulation de l’énergie (CRE), alternative suppliers are calling for this volume to be increased, as it has not changed since 2011, even though their market share has increased;
On a more general note, everyone agrees that ARENH has not led to the emergence of any significant new means of production, and that suppliers are no closer than before to experiencing “free and undistorted competition”. Unsurprisingly, the mechanism has failed.
Finally, the situation is becoming increasingly untenable: the fact that the ARENH volumes requested by suppliers are capped a little more each year to meet the overall 100 TWh cap has a negative impact on consumers. This is because alternative suppliers have to buy the capped volumes on the wholesale market, which has an impact on the prices paid by consumers. 66 . On the other hand, increasing ARENH volumes, as requested by the French Energy Regulatory Commission, would mean agreeing to maintain under perfusion suppliers whose added value for the power system and for consumers is still being sought.
Changing the calculation of the regulated sales tariff to make room for competition
As soon as the electricity market was opened up, alternative suppliers attacked the TRVs, which were challenged by the European Commission as an obstacle to competition.
After obtaining their abolition for business customers, they obtained a complete overhaul of the method for calculating the regulated sales tariff for private customers.
Thus, since 2015, it has no longer been calculated on the basis of the incumbent operator’s production costs, but to approximate the supply conditions of an alternative supplier without production facilities. The energy portion of the tariff therefore reflects:
- The cost of the regulated nuclear price (ARENH at €42/MWh), for around 50% of the energy share.
- The wholesale price smoothed over two years for around 30% of the energy portion.
- And since 2019, the December wholesale price (for delivery the following year), corresponding to the ARENH capped volume (around 20% in 2021) 67 .
This method of calculation pursues the objective of “contestability”, defined by the Commission de régulation de l’énergie as “the ability of an EDF competitor present on or entering the electricity supply market to propose offers on this market at prices equal to or lower than the regulated tariffs”. 68 .
The aim is therefore to ensure that the TRV is high enough to allow competing offers from alternative suppliers. The stated aim is no longer to ensure supply at the best price for the consumer, but to enable alternative suppliers to offer a cheaper deal than the incumbent supplier. The texts thus explicitly organize the artificial increase of the TRV, when market prices are high, with the sole aim of enabling alternative suppliers to be competitive! A very strange way of conceiving competition, which is not without social consequences: the regulated sales tariff still concerns 68% of individual customers. It is the only tariff offered to consumers who have had payment difficulties. It also serves as a benchmark for all offers.
Differentiation in electricity supply focuses on price
Competition was accompanied by a promise – unfulfilled – of lower prices. Alternative suppliers also emphasized the benefits of stimulating innovation and giving consumers a “choice” of offers.
But what to choose, when the technical product delivered in electrical sockets is the same for all? When you consult the offer comparator provided by the French Energy Ombudsman, the selection criteria boil down to the estimated cost “excluding and with promotion/discount and the percentage of green electricity”.
It is this last criterion that enables suppliers to stand out from the crowd by means other than price. However, green offers are based on a system of certificates of origin that is universally denounced.
The false promise of green offers
Green offers are based on Guarantees of Origin (GO), which are supposed to certify the origin of the electricity consumed. Of course, it’s not a matter of choosing the origin of the electricity delivered to the grid at any given moment, since it’s impossible to trace the source of the electrons. Nevertheless, consumers can expect green offers to encourage investment in renewable production.
However, this is not the case: the development of renewable solar and wind energy is due almost exclusively to another, non-market subsidy mechanism: feed-in tariffs, which guarantee producers the necessary visibility in the form of income over the entire amortisation period of their installations. GOs, which take the form of vouchers distributed to renewable producers under certain conditions (and which can be resold on a market), are an inefficient and obscure subsidy mechanism, despite the promise of transparency regarding the origin of the electricity produced. As the same installation cannot claim both the feed-in tariff and the certificate of origin (as this would be a cumulation of two subsidies), the guarantees of origin go mainly to hydroelectric facilities that have already paid for themselves, anywhere in Europe. As one solar producer pointed out in 2019 69 about a quarter of these guarantees of origin correspond to Norwegian hydroelectric production, and some are even located in Iceland, which is not connected to continental Europe!
The Enercoop cooperative points to a few exceptions, very small installations that do not meet the feed-in tariff allocation criteria and for which these certificates could be of interest, but this remains marginal.
For the most part, then, green offers are a sham, a deception of the consumer. EDF, for example, has no qualms about selling green offers that come from the same production facilities as the electricity sold at the regulated tariff, but which is considered to be 100% grey (and therefore not at all renewable)!
The French Energy Regulatory Commission 64 also highlights services designed to help customers consume more intelligently (by avoiding peak hours). In its June 2021 dossier entitled Electricity and natural gas tariffs, it writes in the introduction that consumers now have access to a wide variety of market offers and cites “weekend offers, super off-peak offers, electric vehicle offers, etc.”. These are nothing more and nothing less than offers that have existed for nearly 40 years for industrial customers (green tariffs 15 and 18). Equivalent, simpler offers (because they were sufficient to meet the need for flexibility) have also long existed for individual customers (off-peak tariffs, EJP, Tempo).
In its ” Plea for a return to monopoly “, the CLCV consumers’ association speaks of “zero innovation”, with a “misleading” presentation of “offers” (particularly green offers), offers which “because of their abstract nature […], their complexity and their lack of obvious attractiveness, are conducive to dubious commercial practices”, before concluding: “Beyond the fact that alternative operators have lacked innovation, they are not producers, and when you are not a producer .. it’s harder to innovate”.
In this context of particularly difficult differentiation, it is understandable that alternative suppliers have fought to obtain the means to propose offers cheaper than the regulated sales tariffs… which they have achieved, not by lowering the prices of their own offers, but by pushing the regulated tariffs upwards and making them dependent on wholesale market prices.
On the other hand, with the recent surge in electricity market prices, consumers who had subscribed to offers indexed to these prices found themselves trapped by soaring electricity bills, without having had the impression of making an informed “choice”.
Read more about the lack of differentiation between alternative suppliers’ offers in our fact sheet on the retail electricity market.
Today, the indexation of electricity prices to wholesale market prices is mandatory for all customers.
The results of opening up the market to business customers were very negative: they clearly expressed their wish to keep a regulated sales tariff (see section 4.3). Since then, their representatives have constantly called for stable prices… the opposite of market prices.
For individual customers, the picture is no better. In France, a study by Insee, supplemented after 2016 by TRV increases published by the Commission de Régulation de l’Energie, shows an increase of almost 50% between 2007 (when the market was opened to private customers) and 2021 in constant euros, i.e. once the effects of inflation have been deducted.
Electricity prices for residential customers since 2007 in constant euros (Base 100 in 2007)

Source 2007-2016: INSEE 2019 note ” Les dépenses des Français en électricité depuis 1960 “; 2017-2021: compilation of deliberations by the Commission de régulation de l’énergie on changes to the regulated sales tariff.
Reading: For an electricity price index set at 100 in 2007, this index would rise to 148 in 2021, i.e. an increase of 48% excluding inflation.
The change in the method of calculating the regulated sales tariff has led to all tariffs and offers to consumers being indexed to wholesale market prices. As a result, bill levels have become much more volatile, and uncontrollable by the public authorities. What’s more, the tariff no longer guarantees to cover production costs (which used to be required by law).
This change in calculation method is one of the main causes of the recent increases.
In 2019, for example, TRVs have risen sharply, not because of an increase in production costs, but because of soaring market prices, as the Commission de régulation de l’énergie wrote in its deliberation justifying these tariff increases 70 . The French competition authority (Autorité de la Concurrence) also emphasized this point, noting that these increases had “nothing to do with the rise in EDF’s production costs”. 71 .
Over the last five years (between August 2016 and August 2021), before the gas price surge of 2021, TRV prices have risen by 18% before tax (25% for the energy portion), while production costs in France have not risen significantly. 72 .
Since the beginning of 2021, soaring global gas prices have led to sharp rises in wholesale electricity prices in Europe, forcing governments to intervene to avoid soaring bills. 73 . In its Communication of October 2021, the European Commission transfers responsibility for resolving the problem to the Member States, authorizing them to take fiscal or aid measures (energy cheques, subsidies, tax reductions, etc.).
Northern European countries follow this line, viewing the surge in wholesale prices as a cyclical episode. Even if the 2021 episode is extreme, the evolution of wholesale prices since their inception proves that they have been highly volatile from the outset (see section 3.1). In 2021, the French government, along with other countries, is defending a reform of the retail market while claiming, against all analysis, that the wholesale market is working properly.
Competition also has non-economic impacts
Challenges to public service, including fair treatment of consumers
The multiplication of market offers, supported by numerous suppliers, is breaking down the equality of treatment between consumers that was guaranteed by a single tariff grid. Individual negotiation is generally unfavorable to the most vulnerable consumers, whose lack of support is also the subject of regular alerts from the Energy Ombudsman.
What’s more, users have to contend with suppliers’ canvassing policies, which are deemed aggressive, offensive and misleading by consumer associations, denounced by the Energy Ombudsman and regularly condemned by the courts. 74 .
Hindering the ecological transition
Furthermore, as we have seen, the market price formation mechanism makes it difficult to finance the massive investments required for the energy transition.
One example among many, recalled by economist Dominique Finon: in Bavaria, storage development projects (hydroelectric pumping stations), essential to the energy transition, were halted due to a drop in the price spread between night and day, following the development of photovoltaics. 75 .
Enormous complexity makes the system fragile and opaque
Today, more and more economists and industry specialists are openly admitting it: nobody understands the ultra-complex mechanisms that have been developed in an attempt to adapt the market to the power system.
Such a “thing” is extremely complex and opaque, reminiscent of derivatives in finance, exposing the system to repeated major crises (as derivatives did in 2008). Under the guise of giving citizens a “choice”, this complexity and opacity effectively prohibit any democratic control over energy policy. 76 .
Threat to energy sovereignty
Finally, the competition imposed by the European Union is placing private multinationals at the heart of a sector that is highly strategic in many respects: for access to an essential commodity, for the economy, for regional planning, for tackling the climate emergency.
In a study for the Institut Français des Relations Internationales (IFRI), the authors denounced the economic, strategic and ecological impact of liberalization back in 2016.
Twenty years ago, Europe was at the cutting edge when it came to energy and electricity; today, it’s in retreat. In the 1990s, electricity was both plentiful and affordable, with major industrial groups at the forefront of their fields and world-class electricity operators. Today, Europe’s electricity is more expensive than that of its major competitors, its industrial fabric is losing ground and its electric utilities are in difficulty. […] This abstract, unsystemic vision, implemented over the past twenty years, has produced more than disappointing results in terms of CO2, competitiveness and industrial development.
Conclusion: the market’s unfulfilled promises
The results of two decades of opening up electricity markets confirm that this sector is ill-suited to competition. None of the promises made in the 1996 directive to open up markets, and regularly repeated in subsequent versions, have been kept: “The aim of the internal market in electricity (…) is, by organizing competitive cross-border electricity markets, to offer real freedom of choice to all final customers in the Union (…), to ensure competitive prices, to send the right signals for investment and to offer higher levels of service, and to contribute to security of supply and sustainable development. “(Directive (EU) 2019/944).
The patches and workarounds used to try and remedy the market’s shortcomings have proved insufficient, if not counterproductive:
- For the massive investments required for the energy transition. Over the next thirty years, France’s generating fleet will have to be almost entirely renewed, not only because it is ageing, but also, and above all, to meet the country’s climate objectives. The grid will also have to adapt to the growing share of intermittent renewable energies and new uses for electricity. Most European countries are facing similar challenges. The investments required are massive, as noted in RTE’s latest forward-looking scenarios. But the market is not providing the right incentives. Highly volatile market prices make it impossible to effectively stimulate the heavy investments essential to the energy transition, which require long-term planning and visibility.
- For consumer pricing: market prices don’t offer the necessary stability to individuals and businesses alike, exposing them unnecessarily to significant volatility. What’s more, competition on offers is incompatible with the fair treatment that should apply to a basic necessity. Guaranteed access to energy and support for vulnerable populations are also undermined. Consumers are confronted with aggressive and repetitive canvassing, which has been widely documented.
- For the “freedom of choice” of end customers in the Union. The real choices that citizens have to make when it comes to energy concern, on the one hand, the organization of the energy sector and, on the other, the way we produce and consume energy. These choices are far more important than the alternative between “green offers” and “grey offers”, which has no impact on the energy system. As for the organization of the energy sector, the opaque debates between the European Commission and successive governments deprive citizens of any democratic control. As for the choice of our energy production and consumption patterns, these require citizens’ debates to be organized around scenarios describing possible futures, in particular those of RTE for electricity. 77 which is not the case today.
Consumer associations and producer representatives are calling, more or less covertly, for an exit from the market. 78 . All are calling for long-term price stability.
Faced with this situation, many positions and proposals are on the table.
The European Commission and a majority of EU Member States continue to consider the market and its marginal-cost pricing to be “efficient”. They see the price surge of 2021 as nothing more than a temporary crisis, forgetting previous crises.
In France, but also in other countries 79 more and more players are criticizing the system and seeking to reform it. The French Minister of the Economy, Bruno Le Maire, declared on the set of Public Sénat on September 24, 2021: “The single European electricity market doesn’t work, it’s ‘aberrant’ and criticized its ‘obsolete’ rules.”
A plan to reform EDF and regulate the sale price of nuclear power, known as Hercule 80 has been attempting for the past four years to correct a system that is proving untenable. But the fact that the project has become bogged down in opaque negotiations between the French government and the European Commission is yet another illustration of the impossibility of reforming the market.
At the same time, a growing number of economists, including some of the fathers of open markets such as Paul Joskow, now recognize the serious shortcomings of this organization. They are proposing not to get out of the market, but to circumscribe its perimeter. They advocate the introduction of “hybrid” markets combining market and planning. 81 . EDF Chairman Jean-Bernard Lévy supports this idea 82 and describes a market whose role would be limited to managing the short-term operation of the generating fleet (i.e., determining the merit order call schedule). The market price would never be used, either to remunerate producers or to bill customers. The French Minister of the Economy, Bruno Le Maire, is developing the same idea, proposing to maintain a wholesale market while decoupling retail prices from fossil fuel prices (i.e. wholesale prices). He mentions various price stabilization mechanisms, complex and partial, aiming to return to a pricing system based on electricity production costs for all consumers. 83 .
In any case, a fundamental reform of the electricity system is needed.
Find out more
- Hercules, another step in the electricity market impasse – Sud Energie report (2019)
- Electricity: CLCV pleads for a return to monopoly (2021)
- Futurs énergétiques 2050 study, in particular chapter 11 on economic analysis – RTE (2021)
- Commission de Régulation de l’Energie website
- Electricity sector: from a market regime to a hybrid planning-market regime – La revue de l’énergie (2019)
- EDF Chronique d’un désastre inéluctable, François Soulte Calmann-Lévy (2003)
- Europe de l’électricité, une perspective historique, J.P. Bouttes, F. Dassa, IFRI (2016)
- La construction politique du prix de l’énergie, Sociologie d’une réforme libérale – Thomas Reverdy, Presses de Sciences Po (2014)
- L’organisation des marchés de l’électricité, Report by the Cour des Comptes, 2022
A series of 3 videos from Heu?reka
Appendices
Appendix 1 – Return on investment mechanisms
Remuneration for new energy sources: feed-in tariff and contract for difference
In France, renewable solar and wind energies have always benefited from guaranteed feed-in tariffs. Historically, these tariffs were set by the State, which failed to anticipate falling costs, resulting in substantial overpayments. Today, they are still set by the State for small-scale installations, but are the result of calls for tender. 84 above a certain size. Contrary to what is sometimes claimed, these arrangements are justified even when technologies are mature and “competitive”. Indeed, investing large sums without any guarantee of long-term remuneration would be at best very costly (due to the high risk premium demanded by financiers), and at worst impossible.
Long-term contracts such as Contracts for Difference are also planned for new nuclear power plants. 85 (CFD), as is already the case in the UK for the Hinckley Point plant.
As for investments in hydroelectric facilities, EDF Chairman Jean-Bernard Levy warned that they would not be possible without long-term remuneration guarantees, again of the CFD type. “Without the introduction of a support mechanism, like those applied to renewable energies, the potential of several gigawatts of hydropower in France […] will not be exploited.” 86
Contracts for Difference (CFDs): unnecessary complexity
It’s a mechanism that seems to have been inspired by the Shadocks: rather than setting a guaranteed price, the producer must sell at the market price, and then be compensated upwards or downwards by a public mechanism… to finally receive the set price.

Source Observatoire de l’électricité, Support for renewable energies fact sheet
For example, for a guaranteed price of €49/MWh, if the market price is €53/MWh, EDF will sell its nuclear output on the market at €53/MWh and pay €4/MWh to the French government or a compensation fund. Conversely, if the market price is €40/MWh, EDF will sell on the market and receive €9/MWh from the State (or the compensation fund) to reach the guaranteed price.
So what’s the point of such a gas factory, compared with a simple fixed price?
– It is equivalent to what is collected by the producer and what is billed to the consumer (unless the State decides to pay part of it itself… i.e. the taxpayer).
– It has no effect on the market price, which corresponds to the marginal cost of the generating fleet as a whole, whether or not the producer is remunerated at the market price.
– It has no effect on power plant operation and the incentive not to produce during periods of overproduction (resulting in negative marginal costs): for this, we need to add a capping incentive system that has nothing to do with the CFD.
Historic hydropower and nuclear power: the same need for long-term guarantees
The historic hydro and nuclear power plants were built with a guaranteed income: at the time, regulated sales tariffs were calculated to cover all costs (as required by law). Without this guarantee, their development would have been impossible.
Today, this fleet requires maintenance investments, some of them heavy, which also require revenue guarantees. In the case of nuclear power, the ARENH does not offer this guarantee, since a fall in wholesale prices leads to a fall in the sale price of nuclear power, which has exposed EDF to financial difficulties. Debates over the last few years about the mechanism to replace ARENH seem to be converging towards the establishment of a Contract for Difference (see box above) for historical nuclear power, which amounts to a fixed tariff.
There is also talk of setting up a “hydroelectric ARENH” for the historic hydroelectric park, which would once again involve a fixed price.
Remuneration for gas-fired power plants
Combined-cycle gas turbine (CCGT) power plants are the only generation facilities built with a view to being remunerated at market prices, mainly between 2005 and 2013. 87 These plants were less capital-intensive than others, with shorter payback periods and a higher proportion of variable costs. The experiment ended in failure, however, as the discovery of shale gas in the USA led to a plunge in gas prices, and even more so in coal prices due to a fall in demand. This led to a spectacular fall in marginal costs, and therefore in electricity prices, but also to a reversal in the order of merit between coal and gas, with coal becoming cheaper than gas: gas-fired power plants were called upon less often, and their output fell sharply. This led to a cascade of mothballing of gas-fired combined-cycle power plants and serious financial difficulties for some European producers, such as Germany’s RWE.
The few recently-developed CCGTs, such as the Landivisiau plant, benefit from long-term contracts guaranteeing minimum revenues. Here too, a Contract for Difference guarantees the producer a fixed annual premium of €40 million/year over 20 years, for an investment of €400 million.
Other mechanisms have been introduced to secure revenues from power plants designed to guarantee peak production, in particular Combustion Turbines (TAC gas). These include the capacity mechanism, which offers additional remuneration linked to the provision of available capacity when needed, independently of production. However, this market mechanism also fails to provide the necessary revenue visibility (see box below).
The capacity mechanism
Each supplier must guarantee not only sufficient production to meet customer demand, but also sufficient rapidly mobilizable capacity to cover consumption during peak periods. They can purchase capacity guarantees from producers, particularly those with peak capacity (but also from load shedding operators), which provides them with additional income. These capacity guarantees can then be traded on a market, by auction.
However, this capacity market system only gives a short visibility on revenues, which is insufficient to invest over 20 to 30 years. That’s why the last gas-fired power plant to be built, at Landivisiau, was only able to develop thanks to an income guarantee from the government over its amortisation period.
Appendix 2: Dynamic pricing
Dynamic pricing involves “transmitting market price signals to consumers” to encourage them to adjust their consumption in real time, by shifting it away from peak periods.
A European directive dated June 5, 2019 requires all Suppliers with more than 200,000 sites to develop a Dynamic Pricing offer. In France, the Commission de Régulation de l’Energie imposes three obligations on these offers:
- That the price is at least 50% indexed to the spot market (daily) or to the intraday market.)
- That it reflects price variations at a minimum hourly rate
- That the monthly bill is capped at double the bill for consumption equivalent to the regulated sales tariff.
Yet there have been many warnings: in early 2021, the Energy Ombudsman expressed concern about the financial risks for consumers and urged that these offers be regulated. In the autumn of 2021, the CLCV consumers’ association took four suppliers to court for failing to inform their customers of the risks they were exposing themselves to with such offers.
In Spain, consumers have seen their electricity bills soar as a result of soaring gas prices, as many have offers indexed to the wholesale market. The newspaper El Pais on September 5, 2021 referred to an “intense and bitter debate” over the price of electricity in the country, with “companies and citizens [who] wait daily for the price per MWh on the wholesale market”.
Further afield, in Texas, following a dramatic episode of blackouts caused by an extreme cold snap, prices soared to $9,000/MWh (nearly €8,000), compared with a seasonal average of $50/MWh, and some Texans received bills of $17,000 (€15,000). 88 .
Developers 89 of this dynamic pricing system, which is diametrically opposed to consumers’ demands for stability (from the smallest to the largest), emphasize its benefits for the energy transition by promoting the flexibility of certain consumers. However, no study has been carried out to support or quantify this supposed benefit to the power system.
It’s perfectly legitimate to want to exploit all the system’s flexibilities, in particular by encouraging consumers who can, via pricing, to shift their consumption to off-peak hours. But this does not mean exposing them head-on to the risk of price volatility. This can be effectively absorbed by the community, provided that the aim is to adapt overall consumption to overall production, and not to try to develop potentially lucrative offers, as part of an opportunistic approach. This is the kind of global balance that EDF has been seeking for decades, and was a forerunner at the time, through simple tariffs such as off-peak hours (with well-calibrated peak and off-peak periods). These tariffs, which still capture most of the potential for demand flexibility, can be fine-tuned to adapt to increasing flexibility needs without unnecessarily exposing and constraining consumers.
Appendix 3 – The economic theory on which the market is based is inapplicable
Producer remuneration at the market price is based on a theory 90 which postulates that, under certain conditions, the expected 91 of annual marginal costs is equal to the full annual costs of the generating fleet. According to this theory, a market price based on marginal costs should cover both the variable costs of all means of production (some of which are much lower than marginal production costs, or even zero) and fixed costs. The market price would thus provide the right incentives for investment. 92 in the right means of production, to move towards an economically optimized system. 93 .
The limitations of this theory are well known and predate the development of solar and wind generation. It was used partially and cautiously, and continues to be used by EDF in forward-looking approaches to help with investment decisions in peak production resources (gas-fired power stations in particular) and balancing resources (batteries, for example), as well as in support of the development of regulated sales tariffs. But the regulated sales tariff has never been based on marginal costs.
Whatever the nature of the generating fleet, this theory cannot justify a market based on marginal cost pricing to remunerate producers and bill customers.
For example:
- The theory requires perfect information from the players. They should have an exact view of the variable costs of all power plants, as well as their revenues (i.e. marginal costs), over the entire payback period. This means knowing, at the time of investment, the evolution over the coming decades of fuel prices, other variable costs and market rules, as well as operating times (load factor, depending on the production mix, or even global warming, for example) and even the lifetime of the power plant… The inability to predict the evolution of gas prices, and even the risk of variable costs for gas-fired and coal-fired power plants crossing, are all illustrations of the gap between theory and reality.
- This theory assumes that the choice of investment is made solely on economic criteria, without taking ecological or political constraints into account. The fleet must be “adapted”: each investment must be the result of economic optimization, ensuring that the generating fleet is the one corresponding to the lowest full cost for the defined assumptions. This is necessary, in particular, to ensure that each power plant has sufficient runtimes to earn a return on its investment. However, the generation mix is not simply the result of economic optimization, but depends to a large extent on political choices that take into account other parameters, such as the desire to develop an exportable nuclear industry, the desire to develop renewable energies, or to implement measures to reduce electricity consumption for ecological reasons and energy independence. Market forces would prohibit any such intervention, at the risk of altering the conditions under which power plants are remunerated.
- Each means of production must be independent of the others. However, the operation of hydroelectric dams determines that of downstream hydroelectric and nuclear power plants. What’s more, hydroelectric facilities depend to a large extent, and increasingly so, on external constraints linked to the multi-use of water (minimum/maximum water levels for agriculture, tourism, navigation, etc.).
- The theory ignores most plant operating constraints: nuclear power plants, for example, have start-up and shutdown times, maximum power ramp-up (or ramp-down) gradients, maximum modulation numbers over a given period that vary according to fuel loading levels, and so on.
- The theory works “on average”: if all the conditions are met, the total costs of the system are equal to the expected marginal costs, i.e. the value they should have in the future, on average. In other words, there’s a good chance that, over the lifetime of a power plant, the expected average will not be achieved.
Remuneration depends essentially on the energy sold 94 while costs are largely fixed. This poses a major risk for the players involved, since the return on investment depends not only on the price, but also on the volume of energy sold.
This risk is particularly acute for peak-load facilities such as combustion turbines (historically oil-fired, now gas-fired). Like all means of production, they can only cover their fixed costs at times when their marginal cost is higher than their variable cost. Since these are the generation resources with the highest variable cost, the only times when marginal cost is higher than variable cost are times of failure, i.e. when production is lower than consumption. Some customers have to be cut off, and this missing energy is assigned a very high cost called the failure cost, which forms the marginal cost at these times. Nevertheless, the French electricity system is optimized to present only 3 hours of failure per year… on average. And it’s perfectly possible to remain fault-free for 20 years. 95 . It is impossible for a private investor to accept such a financial risk. Added to this is the fact that, for reasons of social acceptance, the maximum spot market price has been capped at €3,000/MWh, whereas, according to theory, it should be set so as to remunerate the fixed cost of combustion turbines in just 3 hours a year, i.e. around €20,000/MWh. 96 . The capacity mechanism (see box in Appendix 1) was therefore set up to complement and de-risk the remuneration of these peak resources, which could not develop in a pure market.
But the market also fails to reward investment in other production sectors. For example, as EDF Chairman Jean-Bernard Levy reminded us: “No power plant in the world can be built without government support. There is no such thing. 97 .
- The directive also applied to gas, which is not covered in this article (GDF was separated from EDF, merged with Suez and then renamed ENGIE, a company in which the French state now holds just 24% of the capital). ↩︎
- Some countries have not made this choice: in Germany, for example, there is no tariff equalization, and electricity prices differ from zone to zone. ↩︎
- The transmission network (High and Extra High Voltage lines) carries electricity between generation zones and national and regional consumption zones. The distribution networks (Medium and Low Voltage lines) then take over from the transmission network to supply every neighborhood, every street and every building. ↩︎
- More precisely, network operators at European level. In practice, fortunately, they have the levers at their disposal (activation of rapid generation reserves or consumption curtailment, targeted load shedding, etc.) to rapidly restore this balance or limit it to a more restricted area, but the balance remains fragile. ↩︎
- The “Material Footprint” indicator gives an account of all the raw materials used to satisfy a country’s final consumption. ↩︎
- RTE is the French Transmission System Operator, also responsible for power system balance and security of supply. ↩︎
- The results are expressed in the form of six electricity generation scenarios (three without “new” nuclear power [M0, M1 and M23] and three with “new” nuclear power [N1, N2 and N3]) and three demand scenarios: “Reference” with electricity consumption close to the SNBC, “Sobriété” with lower consumption and “Réindustrialisation” with higher consumption. ↩︎
- Nuclear reactors can be shut down for at least 4 reasons: ten-yearly outage programmes, routine maintenance work (in particular to recharge fuel), their “grand carénage” (work to bring them into line with “post-Fukushima” standards and extend their lifespan), and requests from the safety authority in the event of anomalies being discovered. By April 2022, the cumulative effect of all these factors had led to the shutdown of around half of all nuclear reactors. The water shortage could lead to further shutdowns. ↩︎
- Water stored in hydroelectric dams can be turbined at any time to generate electricity. But since volumes are limited and depend on precipitation and snowpack melt, we need to define a strategy for using this water stock for the coming year, in an uncertain universe (as it is highly dependent on climatic conditions) and taking into account multiple constraints (water from dams is not only used to generate electricity), in order to avoid as far as possible the use of expensive and polluting fossil fuels. ↩︎
- E.g.: production modulation speed for dams, reserved flow for other uses (irrigation, fishing, boating, etc.), minimum start-up and shut-down times for thermal power plants, etc. ↩︎
- In economics, a natural monopoly situation exists when the production of a good or service by several companies is more costly than its production by a single company. ↩︎
- Mostly state-owned, the 150 local distribution companies (ELD) are responsible for maintaining and managing the distribution networks and supplying energy at the regulated tariff within their territory (5% of the national territory in total, the rest being provided by Enedis). They may have a marginal production activity (e.g. small hydroelectric power plants). Since the opening up of the market, they can also supply electricity outside their territory, and face competition within their own. The main ones are Electricité de Strasbourg and Gaz et Electricité de Grenoble. ↩︎
- In its report Energy Futures 2050(chapter 11 – Economic analysis, p. 495), RTE estimates investment in the power system at 750 billion euros over the period 2020-2060, including 500 billion for generation and 250 to 350 billion for networks. ↩︎
- European networks distribute all production among all consumers according to physical laws, without it being possible to direct any particular production to any particular consumer: purchase-sale contracts have no influence on these physical laws. ↩︎
- With a mainly local effect: the most frequent outages are observed on rural, overhead networks, which are more sensitive to the vagaries of the weather, falling trees, etc., and also more sensitive to voltage variations (long lines and small cable cross-sections). ↩︎
- Soaring prices in the winter of 2021-2022 have led to the shutdown of certain sites and endangered electro-intensive industries, threatening “150 electro-intensive sites, or 45,000 jobs” according to Agnès Panier-Runacher, Minister Delegate for Industry, (cf. La Voix du Nord, 21/1/2022: “Loon-Plage: le coût de l’électricité menace l’avenir d’Aluminium Dunkerque” or Le Monde, 22/01/2022 “La flambée des prix de l’électricité menace la métallurgie”). ↩︎
- Demand-side management consists in asking players (individuals or companies) to reduce their energy consumption, either voluntarily or automatically, in order to limit a peak in consumption (during periods of extreme cold in winter, for example). Rate-based load-shedding mechanisms (off-peak/peak hours, peak day load-shedding or Tempo rates) have gradually been replaced by market mechanisms, which are a priori less efficient. ↩︎
- Integrated public monopolies in Italy, Portugal, Greece, France, and until 1989 in the UK; local monopolies with separation of production and distribution in Germany and the Netherlands in particular. ↩︎
- See “Europe de l’électricité, une perspective historique”, J.P. Bouttes, F. Dassa, Nov 2016 , IFRI ↩︎
- See, for example, Anna Creti’s article ” Il est fallacieux de reprocher au marché la hausse actuelle des prix de l’énergie “, Le Monde, 15/10/21. ↩︎
- Quoted, for example, by Jean Quatremer in Libération, March 18, 2002 : “Paris welcomes compromise on energy”. ↩︎
- Quoted in La libre Belgique, March 14, 2002. ↩︎
- RTE is the operator and owner of the transmission network (high voltage); Enedis is solely responsible for the distribution network (covering 95% of the country), which belongs to the local “concédantes”. Prior to liberalization, the situation was similar: EDF owned the transmission network, but not the distribution network. ↩︎
- In 2001, CNR took over the management of hydroelectric production from EDF and became a full-fledged operator. It immediately began its merger with Electrabel-Suez, now Engie. At the same time, the company takes over SHEM, the former hydroelectric subsidiary of SNCF. For more details, see Report “Paroles d’expert.e.s d’EDF Hydraulique”, SUD-Energie. SUD-Energie. (2018, 05). ↩︎
- Newbery, Politt, Reiner, Taylor, “Financing low-carbon generation in the UK: The hybrid RAB model“, Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, 2019 ↩︎
- We’ll see later that even when “competitive”, renewable energies still require public support, which is perfectly justified, but for a much smaller amount than the initial subsidies. ↩︎
- See CRE Report, Costs and profitability of renewable energies in mainland France, 2014. ↩︎
- In other words, power plants whose output can be varied, unlike power plants whose output is “fatal” (wind and solar power, for example). ↩︎
- This risk can be illustrated by the threats of production stoppages made by certain large electricity producers in Spain in the summer of 2021, in retaliation for the government’s announcement that it would tax the super-profits made by these producers as a result of soaring prices. See also the major Californian crisis of 2001, caused by price manipulation by private producers (see box, part 3). Or the problems posed by Gazprom’s intervention in the gas sector. ↩︎
- France, for example, is massively dependent on Asia for photovoltaic panels. ↩︎
- See the list on the Enedis website ↩︎
- Unless they are also producers, in which case this is a separate activity. Even then, they produce only a small proportion of the electricity sold to their customers, with the exception of EDF, which accounts for around 80% of French production. ↩︎
- Suppliers’ trading activity consists of buying the electricity they need for their customers on the wholesale markets (see part 3). As prices are highly volatile, they may buy and sell the same electricity several times for a given delivery date, in an attempt to profit from price variations over time. Note that there are also “pure traders”, who simply buy and sell on the market without being either producer or supplier. ↩︎
- The CLCV consumers’ association regularly denounces “the surge in aggressive and misleading canvassing, notably in its Plaidoyer pour un retour au monopole dans le secteur électrique (while accepting the opening up to competition in other sectors such as telephony). ↩︎
- At any given moment, certain power plants may be unavailable for maintenance, or shut down with a minimum shutdown or restart time constraint; nuclear power plants may be constrained by the level of their fuel stock, or by the temperature of the river water cooling the reactors; hydroelectric power plants may be constrained by “reserved” flows to protect aquatic fauna and flora, or for other uses (irrigation, fishing, tourism, etc.), or by an upstream lake level that is too high or too low.) or too high or too low a level in the upstream lake; power plants may be located at points on the grid that cannot be connected to consumption areas, for reasons of line congestion, and so on. ↩︎
- The order of these last two depends on the cost of coal and gas, as well as on the price per tonne of CO2, which indirectly reflects the environmental constraint aimed at limiting CO2 emissions (see the French Ministry’s website for more details); these “commodities” are of course traded on world markets, and their prices may depend on geopolitical considerations. ↩︎
- Estimating this fictitious value, reflecting the potential value of future water use (which could replace gas-fired generation later in the year, for example), is a complex task, since it takes into account the many possible “futures” (depending on weather scenarios – temperature, light, rain, wind -, breakdowns, etc.). It is carried out by dam operators, today mainly EDF in France. ↩︎
- For example, with the EJP (peak-shaving) tariff, EDF has a “stock” of 22 days of shaving to be positioned as best as possible during the winter. ↩︎
- And the price of CO2 on the European ETS market, which penalizes production methods that emit greenhouse gases. ↩︎
- Other elements are also included in the marginal cost, such as the cost of starting up a power plant (spread over the duration of its operation), or the cost of making the most of stocks (water from dams, leverage of shaving on consumption, nuclear power under certain conditions). ↩︎
- The only economic trade-off between means of generation concerns the sizing of gas-fired peaking facilities (combined gas cycles or combustion turbines) and storage. ↩︎
- Some also make the link with a strategy of nuclear deterrence, in a military context. ↩︎
- And even after 2 years, volumes traded on the market are very low. ↩︎
- Caramanis, M. C., Bohn, R. E., and Schweppe, F. C., 1982. Optimal spot pricing: practice and theory. Power Apparatus and Systems, IEEE Transactions on, (9):3234- 3245 ↩︎
- The so-called “infra-marginal rent ↩︎
- See for example (Dominique Finon, 2020), revue de l’énergie : ” Secteur électrique : du régime de marché à un régime hybride planification-marché “ or (A.Lebeau et al., nov 2021) ” Long-term issues with the energy-only market design in the context of electricity decarbonization: Insights from a system dynamics simulation model ” . ↩︎
- A capacity market, a system service market, an interconnection management market, etc. ↩︎
- Non-convex constraints ↩︎
- See for example M. Van Vyve, (Oct.2011) “Linear prices for non-convex electricity markets: models and algorithms”. ↩︎
- To draw up its call program, EDF, for example, simulates a perfect market in a first step. It obtains an initial call schedule, which it then refines in a second stage that only an integrated player (i.e. one with information on all generation plants) can carry out. The result is a final, near-optimal production schedule, significantly better than that obtained from market simulation. ↩︎
- In his 2003 book EDF Chronique d’un désastre inéluctable François Soulte gives numerous examples of the manipulation of electricity markets in various countries (Northern Europe, Spain, UK, Australia, USA, etc.). ↩︎
- This surveillance is much more complex to carry out with several players: in the event of price manipulation, responsibility is diluted and difficult to assign to a particular player. ↩︎
- The Merit Order considers exclusively economic criteria, even if artifacts such as the cost of CO2 emitted can incorporate ecological criteria, notably climate impact. At times when the price of gas is very high and the cost of CO2 insufficient to compensate for the difference with the cost of coal, gas-fired power plants have been shut down in favor of coal-fired plants, even though they emit more CO2. This is what happened very recently (end 2021). ↩︎
- For example, France exports its surplus nuclear generation at night, imports surplus wind and solar power from other countries at certain times of the day, imports gas and coal-fired generation during peak winter consumption periods, and so on. ↩︎
- An entity such as ENTSOE (the European association of transmission system operators), under the supervision of ACER (the association of European regulators), could play this optimizing role. ↩︎
- It has also introduced other financial intermediaries, such as traders (who buy and sell on the market), aggregators (who “group” players together but do not intervene with RTE), etc. ↩︎
- These include the contribution tarifaire d’acheminement, the contribution au service public de l’électricité, the tax on final electricity consumption and VAT. ↩︎
- The idea is to offer consumers cheaper rates at certain times of the year (e.g. at night), when overall consumption is lower, so as to encourage them to shift some of their electricity use to these periods (e.g. running a washing machine). There are also so-called EJP options (Ecrêtement Jour de pointe), with an incentive to consume less during 22 days a year (with one day’s notice). ↩︎
- The consumption of a group of consumers is much more regular than the consumption of each individual taken in isolation: it’s simply a matter of ensuring that each one doesn’t consume at the same time. ↩︎
- For example: basic option for customers who consume regularly all year round, and Peak-Off-Peak for customers who can shift part of their consumption to off-peak hours, especially those with a hot water tank. For industrial customers, up to 8 consumption items were distinguished (crossover between peak and off-peak, weekend and weekday, summer, winter and mid-season). ↩︎
- INSEE Note 2019 “French spending on electricity since 1960”. ↩︎
- See European Commission Decision n°2012/C 398/05, which describes the exchanges between the Commission, the French government and other stakeholders (alternative suppliers, energy-consuming companies) on the various disputes that have accompanied the opening up of the French electricity market. ↩︎
- See theConseil d’État’s opinion of 2019: ” This article [editor’s note: art.5 European directive March 26, 2019] imposes the end of regulated tariffs for the sale of electricity. It only allows sales at regulated tariffs to continue for a transitional period. transitional period which the directive does not specify, only for domestic end customers and micro-businesses “. These regulated sales tariffs are under constant attack, notably from Anode (an association of alternative suppliers), which has devoted a report to the subject. ↩︎
- An independent authority created in 2000, the CRE is responsible for ensuring the smooth operation of the energy market and arbitrating disputes between users and operators. More details on the CRE website ↩︎
- Transitionally increased to 120 TWh in 2022 to limit the impact on bills of soaring wholesale prices. ↩︎
- This pass-through is automatic for customers on the regulated sales tariff (seenext section on calculating the regulated sales tariff). For market offers, even when this is not explicitly provided for in the contract, suppliers must pass on the ARENH volume reduction to remain competitive with the TRV. ↩︎
- This second term appeared in 2018. It is linked to the fact that the total volume accessible to ARENH is limited by the texts to 100 TWh. Since 2019, however, requests from suppliers based on the consumption volume of their customers during low-energy “ARENH hours” have exceeded this 100 TWh volume. They are therefore subject to a capping rate. The volume capped in this way is exposed to December market prices, and at the same time, the share accessible to ARENH decreases (it was 68% until 2018). ↩︎
- CRE Deliberation 2019-028 proposing regulated tariffs for the sale of electricity ↩︎
- Opinion column by Antoine Nogier, President of Sun’R, in Le Echos, 10/04/2019 : “Green electricity: guarantees of origin that guarantee nothing”. ↩︎
- Deliberation Feb 7, 2019 on regulated tariffs tariffs – n°2019-028. ↩︎
- See the press release accompanying the Competition Authority’s notice of March 25, 2019 concerning the setting of TRV prices. ↩︎
- The increase in renewable costs was even without impact on rates, since since 2016 it has been covered by the state budget. ↩︎
- This surge occurred in certain countries, such as Spain, where retail prices were more immediately and directly exposed to wholesale prices, thanks to the introduction of dynamic pricing(see appendix 2). ↩︎
- In 2020, the French national energy ombudsman reported that it was ” increasingly called upon to deal with disputes relating to abusive canvassing” and that it was “ concerned by the increase in fraudulent practices that it is seeing “. ↩︎
- PSL energy economics seminar, Friday January 7, 2022. ↩︎
- Proposals for a public service under citizen control have been made on numerous occasions, and could be enriched by democratic debate. See in particular the SUD-Energie – Paroles d’Expert.e.s report “Hercule, un pas de plus dans l’impasse des marchés de l’électricité “. ↩︎
- But also from ADEME, associations such as NégaWatt, and academic researchers… ↩︎
- See, for example, for individual consumers: ” Électricité : plaidoyer de la CLCV pour un retour au monopole ” (2021). For large consumers, the CEO of Aluminum Dunkerque, an electro-intensive company, stated in La Voix du Nord on 21/1/2022: ” This crisis is indicative of deeper structural difficulties. We need longer-term visibility to be able to continue producing and investing”. See also L’appel pour un service public de l’énergie (signed by numerous political figures, trade unions, associations and economists). ↩︎
- At the meeting of EU energy ministers in Luxembourg on October 26, 2021, Spain, Greece and the Czech Republic, like France, criticized the operation of the electricity market (see AEF info dispatch ). ↩︎
- Consult a number of resources on this subject on the dedicated page of the Sud Energie website, including the report “Hercule, un pas de plus dans l’impasse des marchés de l’électricité” (2019). ↩︎
- See for example Paul Joskow, MIT, May 31, 2021: “From hierarchies to markets and partially back again in electricity”. Dominique Fillon, Revue de l’Energie, 2019 “Secteur électrique: du régime de marché à un régime hybride planification-marché” or Newbery, Politt, Reiner, Taylor, “Financing low-carbon generation in the UK: The hybrid RAB model“, Cambridge Working Papers in Economics, 2019 ↩︎
- Article by JB. Levy published on September 20, 2021 on Linkedin: ” Let’s look further ahead, let’s integrate the long term into electricity prices ” ↩︎
- See Bruno Le Maire’s statement at a Eurogroup meeting on November 8, 2021. ↩︎
- Obligations d’achat, which consisted of a fixed feed-in tariff paid to producers by the French government via an obliged buyer (EDF), have gradually been replaced by complément de rémunération, which corresponds to a contract for difference (see box). For more details, see here. ↩︎
- CFD stands for “Contract For Difference”, also known as “Complément de rémunération” for solar and wind power plants. ↩︎
- Usine Nouvelle (2020, 10 20). ” The complicated future of EDF’s hydroelectric business”. ↩︎
- See the list of commissioning dates here ↩︎
- See for example Au Texas, après la vague de froid, des factures d’électricité à cinq chiffres, Le Figaro (21/02/21) ↩︎
- In particular, the European Commission and the French Energy Regulatory Commission (CRE) ↩︎
- Developed in particular by Caramanis, M. C., Bohn, R. E., and Schweppe, F. C., 1982. Optimal spot pricing: practice and theory. Power Apparatus and Systems, IEEE Transactions on, (9):3234- 3245 ↩︎
- The average of possible future values. ↩︎
- For the park to be adapted, a means of production whose fixed costs are no longer covered by marginal costs would have to be able to “exit” the system, which is impossible. ↩︎
- This theoretical approach was long considered the basis of EDF’s historical “marginal cost” pricing. In reality, the tariff covered the full annual cost of the system, but did not reflect its structure: the variable part of the tariffs was and remains much higher than the variable part of the costs, i.e. the tariff to the consumer depends very largely on his consumption during the billing period (to encourage him to control his consumption), whereas the costs of the system depend essentially on the power subscribed. ↩︎
- Initially, remuneration even depended exclusively on the energy sold. Since the introduction of the capacity market, this is no longer the case. ↩︎
- In a 2015 article for the magazine Contrepoints, the President of the Union Française de l’Energie (UFE) mentioned an ARTELYS study on France and Germany, commissioned by UFE in association with its German counterpart BDEW, which showed that with the current market organization corrected for its shortcomings (no price cap at €3,000, no overcapacity), “an investor in unsubsidized generation has an extremely low expectation of making a return on his investment”. ↩︎
- Some market advocates seize on this argument to say that it’s because these prices are capped that the system doesn’t work… ↩︎
- Comments reported in Les Echos, January 5, 2021: Nuclear power, inflation, Hercules…: the explosive issues that will agitate EDF in 2022 ↩︎