Module

The company in the Anthropocene era

  • By The Other Economy
  • Updated on 26 June 2024

This text has been translated by a machine and has not been reviewed by a human yet. Apologies for any errors or approximations – do not hesitate to send us a message if you spot some!

Introduction

Economic life is based on five main categories of economic agents: households, public administrations, commercial and financial companies and social economy structures. 1 . Companies play an economic role 2 that of producing most of the goods and services that households and public authorities purchase for consumption or investment. To do this, companies employ workers, buy intermediate goods and services from each other, and use public services provided by government agencies. They consume energy and other natural resources, and have an impact on nature.

We’ll see inEssentials 1 that the notion of enterprise is a socio-economic concept distinct from that of company, which is a legal one. This is why we mainly use this term in this module: it is this economic and social dimension that interests us in this module. What’s more, most of our discussion focuses on private companies of a certain size (and relatively little on sole proprietorships).

We’re going to take a look at the usefulness and limitations of business, and respond to some of the most common misconceptions. Are companies part of the problem or part of the solution to the ecological crisis? Are the efforts made in this area real and sufficient, or are they merely a matter of communication or greenwashing? 3  ? Should their legal form and/or governance be transformed so that they make a greater contribution to solving the ecological crisis? These questions are much more acute today than they were 30 years ago, as several planetary limits have been exceeded.

This module is closely linked to the The company and its accounting module, to which reference will be made implicitly or explicitly.

The essentials

What is a company?

The notion of the company, the central object of criticism of capitalism, is more complex than the image conveyed by the media debate on controversial multinationals.

In reality, the nature and longevity of companies are different. 4 and of very different sizes: from the sole proprietorship, to the multinational operating in many different countries and sectors, to the multi-century-old company. They operate in a wide range of regulatory and competitive environments, and have extremely varied modes of governance (e.g. from the highly regulated profession of notary to the highly competitive world of IT services). Their governance, which we discuss in Essentiel 4, can also cover very different situations.

To form an opinion on the current role and responsibility of the company in the ecological crisis and its eventual resolution, it is necessary to clearly define what we are talking about. It is also important to understand that, depending on the players involved, representations and expectations will not be the same.

Depending on the people or stakeholders involved, the company’s perception varies greatly.

For its founders, the company is a means of earning money, practicing a trade and being one’s own boss. It can also be a risky human adventure, a way of turning a dream or an idea into reality. For them, it can be a question of personal fulfillment and social success.

For non-founding managers (or for founders after a few years), the motivations may be a little different: the desire to win a market, to eliminate a competitor, to impose a new product/service, to make the share price soar, to serve a specific shareholder to increase his or her power, and so on.

For the company’s employees, the motivations can be as varied as the way in which the company is viewed. Historically, work has been seen as an inevitability: you have to work to “earn a living”.

Today, motivations can be more complex: being part of a team of friendly colleagues, the pleasure of selling for a salesperson, the need for recognition, the feeling of participating in the company’s project, its “mission” (even if this term is sometimes connoted) and the feeling of participating fully, to the extent of one’s abilities. In return, a salary (and more generally remuneration) is of course expected. The desired level of salary may be based more on considerations of fairness (obtaining a salary equivalent to that of another “comparable” person doing an equivalent job) than on the desire for an ever-higher salary. It all depends on the culture and motivations of the employee in question.

For many stakeholders and observers, a company is first and foremost a social body, a group of people who interact within a collective subject to rules of various kinds: law (company law, labor law, etc.), social customs linked to the country concerned, the company’s organization and specific management methods, the atmosphere resulting from employee interactions and initiatives…

In the region(s) where the company is based, it is seen as a provider of direct and indirect employment, by generating or stimulating activity, whether through local suppliers and service providers, or through the activities that develop to bring goods and services to its employees. It can also be perceived as a source of nuisance (particularly noise and pollution).

For financiers and some managers, the company is simply a set of assets that generate income, with varying degrees of risk, and can be valued over the long term by partial or total disposal. This vision is close to that of the economists who developed the agency theory, according to which the company is a set of contracts (see Idea 2).

For some observers and activists, particularly those who claim to be followers of Marxism and its successors, the company is a place of confrontation between capital and labor, one subordinating the other by definition.

Depending on the vision of the company one adopts, questions of governance and revenue sharing arise and are resolved quite differently, even within the same legal framework.

The company as seen by various scientific disciplines

The various scientific disciplines view the company in terms of their specialization. Mobilizing these different types of representations can help us to understand the factors that block the taking into account of “planetary limits” in corporate strategy and decision-making; these blocks are not necessarily of the order of economic rationality.

Without going into an exhaustive list, let’s take a look at a few examples.

In the field of economics, numerous theories of the firm have been developed. 5

One of the most influential today is that developed by Milton Friedman and the promoters of agency theory, for whom the firm is seen both as a set of contracts and as the property of its shareholders. Institutional economists, on the other hand, see the firm as a social construct and a collective governed by explicit or implicit rules, a point of view we adopt here.

From a sociological and anthropological perspective, the company is seen as a place of alliances, relationships and cooperation, as well as – and above all – of conflict, internal and external warfare. The company is a weapon in the “global economic war” (replacing the battalions of yesteryear): company directors are the “generals” of capitalism.

In a biological approach, the company must have a raison d’être. The terms often used in this register are of the order of life and death: the soul of the company, its DNA, its ecosystem… If it loses this sense, the company is in danger. In this vision, the founder(s) and the seed they planted transcend the company’s history. They are both driving forces and constraints: it will be difficult for successors to implement mutations that go beyond this initial “matrix”.

From a psychological point of view, a company is a theater (and sometimes a place of psychological purging) that stages egos (sometimes inordinate), desires (for enrichment, power, recognition, fulfillment), drives, values, passions, flaws (ranging from lack of certain key skills to sometimes psycho-pathological profiles) from those of the founder(s) to those of all its contributors.

In this conception, the apparent rationality of the company (decisions based on performance and efficiency criteria for its growth) is relatively weak compared to the psychic rationalities of those who create, compose and manage it.

The company as seen by official statistics

Public statistics bodies, such as Insee in France, collect and analyze company data to build up a picture of the country’s productive structure and its evolution over time, and to compare it with that of other countries.

The image of the company and the production system conveyed by these bodies is therefore profoundly structuring, as it serves as the basis for public debate on the subject. That’s why we’ve set out here to understand what we’re talking about.

The company as a socio-economic reality

But how do you define the outline of a company? This is not as trivial a question as it might seem. The answer will vary according to the size and complexity of the organization concerned.

At first glance, one might think that a company is defined by its legal existence. Indeed, for a long time it was confused with the “legal unit” (see box below).

Such a definition, however, is restrictive and poorly reflects economic reality.

As Insee explains, “many legal units are not autonomous: they belong to a larger whole, which groups together several units and which holds decision-making power, notably over the allocation of production factors or research and development”. It is this whole that we call a company, and which makes economic sense. 6

Finally, a company is also a work collective, a social body. This is why the notion of “enterprise” is often found in the French Labor Code, where the term is interpreted as a group of workers carrying out a common activity under the authority of a single employer.

An establishment is a unit of production of goods and services (market or not) located geographically on a given territory (e.g.: a bakery, a warehouse, a farm, an industrial production site, an “office” of a consulting firm). It is legally dependent on a legal unit. See Insee and Eurostat definition.

A legal unit (UL) is a legal entity under public or private law (company, sole proprietorship, administration, local authority, association, etc.). 7 It may be a legal entity or a natural person (a self-employed person, for example). It may have one or more establishments (e.g. a chain of bakeries, supermarkets, etc.). In 2020, 95% of ULs in France will be single-establishment. See the Insee and Eurosta t.

A group is a set of companies (one of the legal forms ULs can take) linked together by legal and/or financial ties and controlled by the group head. A group is said to be multinational when at least two of its constituent companies are located in different countries. See the definition .

The “enterprise” is the smallest combination of legal units that constitutes an organizational unit for the production of goods and services, enjoying a certain degree of decision-making autonomy, notably for the allocation of its current resources.”

Insee 8 See Eurostat definition.

A company can therefore be an independent legal unit or a group. In France, all ULs and their establishments are identified in the SIRENE register.

Source Les différents niveaux et champs d’observation de l’appareil productif en France – Les entreprises en France Édition 2023 – Insee

How many companies in France?

To analyze the production system, we need to focus on the commercial sector, and have access to consistent, harmonized accounting data.

Insee has thus defined the scope of structural business statistics (also known as the “non-agricultural, non-financial market sectors”), from which the following are excluded:

  • the agricultural (except forestry) and financial (except holding companies and financial and insurance auxiliaries) sectors, as their accounting is not homogeneous with the other sectors.
  • non-market activities (carried out by public administrations or associations).
  • non-productive activities

In France, there are 4.5 million businesses in the non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors (2021).

combien-entreprises-en-france

Source Les différents niveaux et champs d’observation de l’appareil productif en France – Les entreprises en France Édition 2023 – Insee and L’essentiel sur… les entreprises – Insee 2024

Companies are not necessarily corporations

When we talk about a company, we often equate it with a corporation. Yet the two concepts are quite different.

As we saw in the previous section, a company is a socio-economic reality whose legal basis is one or more legal units.

The company is one of the forms that a legal entity can take, but it is not the only one (see definition below). Sole proprietorships are also very numerous. It’s important to understand this, as debates about business often focus on corporations, with their specific governance structures (power and value sharing) and objectives.

While INSEE unfortunately does not make public information on the legal categories of the 4.8 million legal units (and a fortiori companies) included in the scope of structural business statistics, we can nevertheless draw some orders of magnitude from the data on all 7.6 million legal units.

At the end of 2021, of the 7.6 million legal units in France, over 55% are sole proprietorships (approx. 4.2 million), 37.6% are companies (approx. 2.8 million) and 3% are associations (approx. 236,000). The “Other” category includes in particular public administrations (state administration, local authorities, social security administrations, etc.).

repartition-unités-legales-s selon-la-categorie-juridique

Source Les différents niveaux et champs d’observation de l’appareil productif en France – Les entreprises en France Édition 2023 – Insee

The scope of structural business statistics essentially covers sole traders and companies. However, some sole traders and companies belong to the agricultural and financial sectors and are therefore excluded. Others may have no productive activity at all. 9 Some non-trading companies have no commercial activity. 10 Some structures listed under “Other”, such as such as public enterprises, may be included.

It is therefore not possible to fully deduce from the above statistics the legal form of the companies included in Insee’s structural statistics. However, we can assume that at least one out of every two businesses is a sole trader.

  • Sole proprietorships

These are companies created in their own name: they have no legal personality separate from their founder. Until very recently, sole traders were liable for company debts on their own assets (apart from their main residence). Since the law in favor of independent professional activity of 2022, only the elements necessary for their professional activity can be seized in the event of professional default.

Among individual entrepreneurs, there is a specific status: that of micro-entrepreneur (called auto-entrepreneur until 2014), which offers streamlined business start-up formalities and simplified calculation and payment of social security contributions and income tax.

  • The companies

The notion of company is defined in article 1832 of the French Civil Code.

“A company is formed by two or more persons who agree by contract to allocate property or their industry to a joint venture, with a view to sharing the profits or benefiting from any savings that may result. In the cases provided for by law, it may be set up by an act of will by a single person. The associates undertake to contribute to any losses.

A company is therefore a legal entity resulting from a legal act whose primary objective is to make profits for those who created it. 11

There are many different types of company, which can be grouped into two broad categories with different implications for their founders:

Partnerships are characterized by the importance of the collaboration of the partners who have created (or joined) the company. In return for the resources they contribute to form the company’s capital, they receive financial securities known as shares, the transfer of which is subject to strict controls. 12 (unlike shares). This is one way of preventing capital dilution. Partners are jointly and severally liable for the company’s debts. This means that one partner can be sued for another’s debt, and that partners are liable on all their personal (and not just professional) assets. Trust between partners is therefore essential.

The legal forms of partnership in France are the société en nom collectif (SNC), the société en participation and above all the civil partnership These include the SCI (société civile immobilière) for property management, and the SCP (société civile professionnelle) for regulated professions (notaries, lawyers, auditors, doctors, etc.).

The joint-stock companies are more focused on the securities issued than on the partners themselves. The initial contributions to form the capital take the form of financial securities, shares, which the associates (or shareholders) are free to issue. 13 (including on a stock exchange, if the company is listed). Moreover, the liability of associates is limited to their contribution, and they are not jointly and severally liable.

The main forms of joint-stock company in France are the SA (société anonyme) and the SAS (société anonyme simplifiée). SARLs are considered mixed or hybrid companies. 14

This initial overview shows that a company is not necessarily a corporation, although the two terms are often confused. The former is a socio-economic concept used to analyze the production system, while the latter is a legal status with very specific characteristics.

Companies come in all sizes, ages and weights in productive activity

Statistics on companies are extremely rich. For example, they enable us to understand their enormous diversity, whether in terms of size, sector of activity or impact on the productive system. However, as we often point out in The Other Economy, we also need to take a step back from the figures to understand the values behind the different ways of counting.

The production structure is highly concentrated

A common way of observing the world of companies is to differentiate them by size, in order to assess their weight in the productive fabric in terms of various indicators (number, employment, sales, added value, exports, etc.). Thresholds have been defined for this purpose since 2003 at European Union level (member states are required to respect maximum thresholds, with some leeway).

Thresholds for classifying companies by size in the European Union and France

The main differences between the two classifications lie in the fact that the European Union has created more subdivisions within SMEs, while France has chosen to distinguish between ETIs and large companies.

categories-companies-european-union-france

Source In a 2003 Recommendation, the European Commission defined thresholds for categorizing companies according to headcount and financial data (sales or balance sheet total). France transposed the Commission’s recommendations in a decree implementing the 2008 Law on the Modernization of the Economy.

Be careful not to confuse the microenterprise (MIC) referred to here, which is a statistical concept and can take the legal form of a sole proprietorship or a company, with the status of microentrepreneur (discussed inEssentiel 1.4), which is a specific status of sole proprietorship in France.

The workforce corresponds to the number of “persons employed”. It includes company employees and non-employees (owner-managers, highly invested partners, persons treated as employees under national law). 15

Some indicators of France’s production structure by company size

In 2021, the 4.5 million companies in France’s non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors will generate 1,296 billion euros in added value and employ 14.7 million full-time equivalent (FTE) workers, bringing the total number of jobs in France to around 30 million.

key-data-apparatus-productif-en

Source L’appareil productif français en 2021– Les entreprises en France Édition 2023 – Insee

Scope: non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors. For a definition, see Essential 1.3 How many companies in France?

As can be seen from the graph below, France’s productive fabric is highly concentrated. While small and medium-sized businesses will account for 96% of companies (4.3 million) in 2021, their weighting is much lower in terms of number of employees (18%) and added value (19%). Conversely, the 300 or so large companies account for 28% of employees and 33% of added value.

France’s production base is highly concentrated (2021)

key-data-apparatus-productif-en-percentage

Source L’appareil productif français en 2021– Les entreprises en France Édition 2023 – Insee

Scope: non-agricultural, non-financial market sectors (for definition, see Essentiel 1.3 How many companies in France?).

The French situation is not exceptional in Europe. Everywhere, MICs dominate in terms of number of companies. ETIs and large companies generate around half of added value. In terms of employment, the situation is more contrasted: TMCs account for just under a third of the workforce in the European Union, but only 19% in Germany and 43% in Italy.

Comparison of production structure in different European Union countries by company size

comparison-productive-system-ue

Source Eurostat – Company statistics by NACE Rev. 2 size class and activity (consulted in June 2024)

Scope: industry, construction and market services (this scope is roughly equivalent to that of the non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors used by INSEE).

Please note that the employment indicator used is the number of people employed. 15 (the headcount indicator), whereas Insee uses the FTE employee indicator (not all employees are salaried).

Other types of information available: sectors, company demographics, etc.

Statistical institutes provide a wide range of other data for analyzing the productive fabric. For example, it is possible to analyze the weight of different economic sectors in terms of sales, added value, employment, investment, exports, etc.

Main aggregates by business sector in 2021

main-aggregates-by-industry

Source Mainly non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors – Companies in France 2023 Edition – Insee

It should be noted that the mainly non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors include 3.7 million companies with sales of 4142 billion. They therefore constitute a sub-section 17 of the structural statistics field used by Insee (which we defined inEssentiel 1), which comprises 4.5 billion companies with sales of 4241 billion.

There are also statistics on the “demography” of businesses, because they don’t last forever. For example, in France, 61% of companies created in 2014 were still active five years after their creation. 18 . This means that 40% of companies “die” within 5 years of their creation. 19 .

Find out more

Each year, Insee produces a comprehensive publication on Companies in France.

For the European Union, the Eurostat statistics explained website offers a comprehensive section.

The need to step back from statistical data

As is often the case in The Other Economy, we’d like to emphasize the importance of taking a step back from statistics. Although they are based on concrete data collected from economic players, they are nevertheless subject to conventions, i.e. choices made by statisticians according to reasoning and justifications that cannot be totally objective in terms of describing reality.

The scope observed by statistical bodies is not neutral

Insee’s Les entreprises en France – Édition 2023report is intended to provide “a comprehensive structural view of our production system”.

As we saw inEssential 1.3, structural business statistics cover the “non-agricultural and non-financial market sectors”, which in 2021 comprised 4.5 million businesses, corresponding to 4.8 million legal units.

Insee, however, lists nearly 7.6 million active legal units in France. The transition from one figure to another has involved making choices, adopting conventions justified by technical considerations (exclusion of most agricultural and financial structures, as their accounting systems differ from those of other sectors) or without justification (exclusion of non-market activities).

However, given that our ambition is to analyze the productive system, the exclusion of agricultural production, financial services and all non-market activities raises questions. Are public services such as education, health, justice and policing not considered to be part of productive activity? And what about the contribution of hundreds of thousands of associations? These are legitimate questions, as these choices send out a biased message about what makes up a country’s productive fabric.

It is interesting to compare the figures for the production system defined by INSEE with those for the economy as a whole.

Non-market production, for example, will account for just over 11% of total French production in 2021. 20 and that’s without counting all the services that are not subject to any monetary transaction (for example, the work of France’s 12 million volunteers).

Value added amounted to 2,217 billion euros. 21 that same year. With 1,296 billion euros of added value, the French production system as defined by INSEE represents less than 60%. The same type of analysis is enlightening when it comes to employment (see Misconception 1 : only companies create wealth and jobs).

Of course, the agricultural, financial, non-profit and public administration sectors are also subject to statistical analysis. But the angle is not the same. In the case of government agencies, for example, the question of public finances (expenditure, debt and deficit) is given much greater prominence than that of their contribution to the productive system. This issue is also well illustrated by the social and solidarity economy (SSE), which lies at the interface between the market and non-market sectors, due to the multiplicity of structures that make it up. Although statistics on this subject are still sketchy, it is clear that this part of the economy, which focuses more on social purpose than profit, accounts for a substantial proportion of activity, particularly in terms of employment (see Essentiel 4 on governance).

Slowly evolving statistical conventions were not designed to capture the material dimension of production.

Statistical conventions are usually drawn up within a regional (European Union) or even international framework. They correspond to the needs of the time, and take a long time to evolve.

The example of the sectoral division of the economy is illuminating in this respect. Created in 1993, the NAF (nomenclature d’activités françaises) is “a nomenclature of productive economic activities, primarily designed to facilitate the organization of economic and social information”. It has the same structure as the European activity nomenclature (NAVE Rev2), itself derived from the international nomenclature. It has been revised twice, in 2003 and 2008.

Developed at a time when ecological issues were barely present in public debate, this nomenclature did not take into account the consumption of natural resources and pollution linked to economic activities. Other nomenclatures were therefore developed to deal with these issues, such as the one that structures the major sectors of the economy to account for the main sources of greenhouse gas emissions. The correspondence between the two, and therefore the analysis of the production system in terms of these emissions, is not obvious.

The company: a place of cooperation and tension between multiple internal and external players

Companies are part of an institutional, human and natural environment

A company cannot function, let alone grow, without multiple tasks of different kinds being carried out, internally by employees or externally by service providers or suppliers.

It also depends on free or paying public services and the availability of infrastructures (transport, energy, waste, telecoms) and quality institutions (education and training, health, justice, legal system, etc.). It is embedded in human (stakeholders) and/or natural (environment) “ecosystems”.

It is subject to numerous legal obligations: labor law, corporate and tax law, environmental law, business (or contract) law, intellectual property law and competition law. There are also certain sectors that are subject to specific regulations (e.g. in France: banking, insurance, bookshops, the press, etc.) and regulated professions that are subject to specific obligations. 22 ).

Lastly, we remind you that certain activities are prohibited or even criminalized. 23 . They are not necessarily economically anecdotal, and some of them are included in the GDP (see our module GDP, Growth and Planetary Resources – Sub-section How are the limits of production defined?)

Different functions are implemented in the company

The “company manager” (one person or several partners) embodies and defends the company’s project in the eyes of its customers, employees and other stakeholders. He or she is also the conductor of an orchestra, ensuring that the functions to be carried out are carried out “adequately” (i.e. at the required level of quality for an appropriate cost), and that the company fits into the ecosystem(s) with which it interacts. It is an arbiter of the many conflicts that the company experiences. So he’s not just a manager, an accountant or a director.

Let’s take a quick look at what it takes to make a business work.

A company, whatever its size, carries out a wide range of functions in-house, or has them carried out by suppliers or service providers. The number of staff assigned to each function depends not only on the size of the company, but also on its “mission” and business model.

What is a business model?

The expression business model 24 refers to the way in which a company is expected to make a profit. The most common business model is obviously the production and sale of margin-generating products or services. But there are others. The “free” press, for example, is a specific business model, in which advertising is the main source of revenue, creating biases in the choice, production and presentation of information. Another example is that of certain digital giants such as Google, which offer free services to their users and derive most of their revenue from the sale of targeted advertising based on the exploitation of these same users’ personal data.

The business model, like strategy, is a crucial aspect in the success or failure of a company. History shows us a large number of failures or successes strongly linked to the business model. The print media, with its recurrent economic difficulties, is an emblematic example.

Financiers (bankers, investors) need to understand the business model(s) of the companies in which they invest, and their sensitivity to external or internal factors. A lack of understanding of what drives a company’s profits is indeed very risky.

Source To find out more, see the video Understanding business models in 5 minutes on Xerfi Canal.

Here is a brief list of the functions performed within the company, and embodied in different ways depending on the case:

  • defining the “mission” and the strategy for the more or less long term;
  • sales (marketing, advertising, sales department, customer relations, business development) ;
  • external and internal communication (with or without the press and news media) ;
  • Human resources and social management: payroll, social declarations, occupational medicine, relations with staff representatives, recruitment, training, early skills management, sickness management, leave and departures (resignations, individual and collective redundancies);
  • production (and supporting services), subcontracting and purchasing;
  • IT management (software and hardware) ;
  • accounting and financial management: company financing (credit, shareholders, markets), cash management, accounting, management control, communication and financial reporting
  • legal: labor law, corporate and tax law, environmental law,
  • business (or contract) law, intellectual property and competition law, etc.
  • fundamental or applied research and the development of new products and services;
  • public relations: relations with political and administrative authorities at the relevant level, professional organizations, NGOs, and the possibility of influencing these players;
  • monitoring and controlling the company’s social and environmental responsibility.

The company is not isolated

It is part of a network of stakeholders: customers, employees, suppliers, government and public authorities, shareholders, investors, bankers. It operates in one or more territories, has neighbors and benefits from public services and infrastructures.

Businesses cannot live and develop without the implicit approval of the public, the so-called “social license to operate”; they must have a certain legitimacy that is not reduced to respect for the law, nor to the fact that they can find solvent customers. This social pressure is exerted on managers and imposes de facto limits on them.

On a more prosaic level, companies need to inspire long-term customer confidence in the quality of their products and services, and in their ability to live up to the claims they make. Increasingly, they are being questioned on their social and environmental practices.

As the following extract from wave 11 of the Political Confidence Barometer (2020) shows, large private companies often inspire only lukewarm confidence.

In France, a Pinocchio prize was created to denounce “greenwashing”. Online applications such as MoralScore evaluate companies according to various criteria (environment, social contribution, privacy, working conditions, etc.). Students are increasingly reticent about, and even reject, certain large companies and groups, which is reflected in growing recruitment difficulties.

As can be seen in the barometer below, managers of large companies tend to have a poor image with the public, unlike managers of SMEs.

barometre-relation-des-francais-a-lentreprise

Source Baromètre de la relation des Français à l’Entreprise – An Elabe survey for the Institut de l’Entreprise – Edition 2023

The company, a crossroads of cooperation and conflict

The company is first and foremost a place for cooperation – that’s its raison d’être.

If a company is created, it’s because its creator(s) believe that the pooling of skills and financial capital they imagine will be more effective than their individual actions, even if organized by contracts.

Within the company, cooperation is effective, necessary and encouraged by the very principle of organization. Relationships between employees are not generally the subject of precise contracts, and everyone has room to manoeuvre. Even if individual interests are by no means absent, the company stimulates cross-services: you can do me this favor, but you have to do me that favor…

The company is also a place of conflict and tension:

  • between the “boss” and the employees, the former having to embody the interests of the company (and sometimes of the capital owners), sometimes to the detriment of certain employees;
  • between the company and its suppliers/service providers, where each has opposing interests (suppliers want to sell as well as possible to their customer (the company), who wants to buy as well as possible…);
  • between employees, where the limits of cooperation can be revealed when it comes to pay rises, bonuses, promotions and power.

The art of management (thousands of books, seminars and training courses are sold worldwide on this subject) is precisely that of encouraging cooperation without annihilating emulation, initiative and the recognition of those who contribute most and best to the company achieving its objectives. It is also the art of arbitrating the inevitable conflicts that arise within the company.

Trade unions and employee representatives

In most cases, the company is run by the representatives of its shareholders (seeEssentiel 4 on the different forms of corporate governance). 25 ). Employees are represented in and around companies by structures charged with defending their interests, taking part in certain negotiations and, where necessary, engaging in a power struggle with management. This reality has been built up over time, and did not emerge spontaneously. Moreover, these structures have varying degrees of weight and power, depending on the era and the country.

The development of trade unionism has made it possible to win social rights

Capitalism in the 19th and early 20th centuries evolved in social terms, mainly as a result of conflicts over social rights.

The 1880s marked the birth of trade unionism in Europe, in a period marked by the notion of class struggle (between proletariat and employers). It developed on large industrial sites, where human labor was progressively fragmented to increase productivity, then increasingly mechanized, automated and finally robotized. By engaging in a power struggle with governments, notably through strikes, the unions helped achieve social progress and improved working conditions.

Milestones in social progress in France

  • 1841: Ban on child labor for children under 8.
  • 1864: Right to strike tolerated.
  • 1874: Creation of the labor inspectorate.
  • 1884: Waldeck-Rousseau law authorizing the creation of trade unions.
  • 1892: Women’s working hours limited to 11 hours and prohibited at night.
  • 1898: Liability of the company manager in the event of a workplace accident.
  • 1900: Working time limited to 10 hours.
  • 1906: Law introducing Sunday rest (which had been abolished in 1880).
  • 1910: Workers’ pensions financed by employees, employers and the State.
  • 1919: Working hours limited to 8 hours.
  • 1936: Forty-hour week, paid vacations, right to organize freely, introduction of employee delegates, law on collective labor agreements.
  • 1941: Introduction of the pay-as-you-go pension scheme and the minimum old-age pension.
  • 1944: Creation of the general social security system in accordance with the program of the National Council of the Resistance.
  • 1946: Recognition of the right to employment and the right to strike in the preamble to the constitution of the Fourth Republic (taken up in that of the Fifth Republic).
  • 1950: Introduction of the guaranteed interprofessional minimum wage (SMIG), which became the interprofessional minimum growth wage (SMIC) in 1970.
  • 1956, 1963: 3rd and 4th weeks of paid leave.
  • 1982: 5th week of paid leave + law on the 39-hour week + Auroux laws on the right of expression and collective bargaining.
  • 1983: Legal retirement age of 60.
  • 1986: Creation of the Revenu minimum d’insertion.
  • 1998: 35-hour week (Aubry Law)
  • 1999: Universal health coverage.

Source Find out more on Wikipedia’s Social policy in France page

Union power was still very strong during the 30 Glorieuses (1945-1975), with notable differences between countries: some, particularly in Northern Europe, had much higher rates of unionization than others.

Unionization rates, 1961 – 2000

weight-union-different-countries

Source Trade Union Density in International, Institute for Economic Research, Munich, 2004

Share of union members among employees, 10-year average.

Over the last few decades, unionization rates have been falling almost everywhere (see OECD unionization database 2000-2020). This is particularly the case in France, where the rate plummeted from the end of the 1970s to stagnate at around 10%. 26 . In addition, a 2017 study by the Ministry of Labor’s Statistics Directorate (DARES) shows the weakening of employee participation in trade union activities, with a clear drop-off around 2010.

The causes of union decline are varied and differ from country to country:

  • the decline of industrial and manufacturing activities, increasing outsourcing to large groups and the development of temporary work are all factors preventing workers from joining forces;
  • cultural and ideological changes (with increasing individualization and consumerism in society, and a more general decline in militant activities);
  • programmatic changes within political parties, working conditions and remuneration, and “social” legislation;
  • the low representativeness of trade unions in countries like France, where they represent fewer and fewer employees.
In parallel with the development of trade unionism, social legislation has increased the role of employee representatives within the company.

In most cases, however, this role remains limited. In the French example detailed here, employee representatives have the power of expression (and not necessarily of all employees, either…), not always of consultation and even less of co-determination or co-decision.

Although the French Labor Code, which dates back to 1910, has never ceased to evolve, the Auroux laws of 1982 modified more than a third of it. These texts, comprising 2 ordinances and 4 laws, strengthened employees’ right to express their views on working conditions, endowed the works council with an operating budget, enshrined the obligation of annual collective bargaining, and created the health, safety and working conditions committee (CHSCT), as well as the right of withdrawal.

The last major reform of labor law dates back to 2017 with the Macron ordinances which, on a general level, introduced less favorable labor law for employees. These ordinances also merged the various existing representative bodies(staff delegates, CHSCT and works council) into a single body the Social and Economic Committee (CSE), mandatory in all companies with more than 11 employees.

The main role of the CSE is to present employees’ individual or collective complaints to the employer (wages, collective bargaining agreement, application of the Labor Code), and to promote good working conditions. The CSE can also investigate workplace accidents or occupational illnesses, refer matters to the labor inspectorate, and has a right of warning (in the event of infringement of personal rights or health, in situations of serious and imminent danger, as well as in matters of public health and the environment).

In companies with at least 50 employees, it must be consulted on certain issues relating to the life of the company, its strategy and employment. 27 but the employer is free to decide whether or not to take this opinion into account.

Environmental issues were a late entrant to employees’ right of expression

CHSCTs had to be convened in the event of a serious event linked to the establishment’s activity that had (or could have) harmed the environment and employees. In 2017, the creation of the CSE extended the right to alert to environmental damage.

The Climate and Resilience Act (art. 40) of 2021 expands the missions of the CSE by specifying that in companies with at least 50 employees, it ensures a collective expression of employees on the decisions of the company’s managers “particularly with regard to [their] environmental consequences” (art. L2312-8 of the French Labor Code). Lastly, the challenges of the ecological transition are included in negotiations on forward-looking management of jobs and skills (GPEC).

The challenges and variety of Governance

As we saw inEssential 1, a company is first and foremost a socio-economic reality. Its legal basis can be either a natural person (individual entrepreneur), or one (or more) legal entities (company, cooperative, mutual, etc.). We are mainly interested in legal entities here, since corporate governance implies the existence of a collective structure.

We have defined corporate governance as “a set of legal, regulatory or practical provisions that delimit the scope of the power and responsibilities of those charged with guiding the company in the long term”, on the understanding that guiding the company means “taking and controlling decisions that have a decisive effect on its sustainability and hence its lasting performance”.

Pierre-Yves Gomez (2018)

We’ll see that governance involves different types of power, and that depending on the legal form of private companies, shareholders play a more or less important role.

The four powers of governance

In his book, La gouvernance d’entreprise (PUF, 2018), Pierre-Yves Gomez breaks down governance-related responsibilities into four powers, which are represented in the diagram below.

This typology enables him to analyze each organizational governance according to two key questions: who holds each of these powers, formally or tacitly? How are these powers exercised by the people who hold them?

The 4 powers of corporate governance

the-four-powers-of-governance

Source Benchmark of new governance models, Heart Leadership University and Prophil (2022)

The constituent power sets all the laws and rules establishing the framework within which corporate governance can be exercised. This mainly concerns the national and international legal framework. This power is therefore mainly exercised by the public authorities, in particular the State.

Sovereign power is that which founds the others – respecting the constituent power – and ensures their continuity. It is held by shareholders in the case of companies, by members in the case of cooperatives or mutual societies, and by members in the case of associations. Its prerogatives include, in particular, validation of annual accounts, management by the executive and appointment of directors (who have supervisory powers).

The function of the supervisory board is to administer the organization, which implies, in particular, responsibility for appointing its managers (holders of executive power), selecting strategic orientations from among those proposed by them, and monitoring results. This power is exercised by the Board of Directors or the Supervisory Board.

Executive power is exercised by the organization’s manager(s). Its role is to define and implement strategy. It is accountable to the holder of sovereign power.

What is the “classic” governance of private companies?

A company is formed by two or more persons who agree by contract to allocate assets or their industry to a joint venture, with a view to sharing the profits or benefiting from any savings that may result. In the cases provided for by law, it may be instituted by the will of a single person. Partners undertake to contribute to losses.

Definition of a company – Art. 1832 of the Civil Code

The purpose of the company is to generate profits for its founders. For some economists, such as Milton Friedman, leader of the Chicago school of economics 28 some economists, such as Milton Friedman, leader of the Chicago School, have even made maximizing shareholder profits the company’s sole objective.

A shareholder-friendly environment

We’ll see how this objective is reflected in the concentration of power (sovereign, supervisory and sometimes executive) in the hands of shareholders. This does not mean that all companies are guided solely by the pursuit of “value creation” for shareholders, but that the general provisions make such an objective possible. This has become the largely dominant situation for large listed companies.

Sovereign power is held by the general meeting of shareholders, each of whom has generally proportional voting rights. 29 to the shares of the company’s share capital they hold (see our capital factsheet for more information). This meeting votes on the annual financial statements, validates past management and future projects, and elects the members of the Board of Directors (BOD), which holds supervisory power. 30 .

Directors have extensive powers, specified in the Articles of Association. At the very least, the Board elects its Chairman from among its members, appoints the company’s Chief Executive Officer to exercise executive power, and oversees the company’s management. In some companies, these two functions are performed by a single person, the Chairman and CEO.

This general framework can give rise to very different situations depending on how each of these powers is allocated and exercised.

For example, in a family-run business, power is often concentrated in the hands of the founder and possibly those closest to him. This is very different from a public limited company, where shareholders often have no connection with the company’s creation. Moreover, depending on the concentration of shareholders (e.g., a few large shareholders with almost all the voting rights, or at the other extreme, a very diffuse shareholder base with a multitude of small shareholders), the exercise of governance will not be the same.

In some cases, the constituent power has given employees a much greater role.

In Germany (and many other European countries), under various provisions 31 ) the “co-determination has been in place since the 1970s: employees are represented on the Board of Directors, and can account for up to 50% of members (for companies with over 2,000 employees). However, they never have a majority (the Chairman’s vote counts double), and so cannot take decisions without the agreement of at least one director representing the shareholders.

In France, in companies employing over 1,000 people, employees appoint one or two directors to represent them, with the same duties and responsibilities as shareholder representatives.

It’s important to distinguish between co-determination (where employees hold part of the supervisory power via their representatives on the Board of Directors) and employee representation bodies within the company, which usually only have consultative powers. In France, the Comité social et économique (CSE) is only consulted in certain specific cases. Moreover, the employer is not obliged to take account of the opinion given.

Governance of social economy structures

While there is no formal definition of SSE, there is a fairly broad consensus on the concept’s contours. According to the OECD, the SSE encompasses a group of organizations whose activities are “motivated by the achievement of societal objectives, by the values of solidarity, the primacy of people over capital, and, in most cases, by democratic and participative governance”. 32

In France, the legal framework laid down by the 2014 law on the social and solidarity economy captures this well. The SSE is “a mode of enterprise and economic development adapted to all areas of human activity” to which companies choose to adhere subject to compliance with several conditions:

  • pursue an objective other than profit sharing ;
  • democratic governance, provided for in the articles of association ;
  • profits or “surpluses” are mainly used to maintain or develop the company’s business, and compulsory reserves cannot be distributed.

In simpler terms, the SSE is characterized by its focus on people and by the limitation of profit-making (for the proportion of SSE structures that are for-profit).

SSE companies are at the service of people, and emphasize this; they do not have to pay capital and are not run by representatives of funding providers.

This limited profit-making status protects SSE structures from disposals and other restructurings linked to “capital-intensive” operations (i.e. those whose main aim is to generate value for shareholders or owners of shares).

However, this also means that these structures are unable to attract massive amounts of household savings, as they do not remunerate either the risk, the deprivation of the immediate use of the money invested, or the opportunity cost (the gain linked to alternative investment options).33

What are the structures of the social economy?

The law distinguishes between :

  • statutory players that automatically come under the SSE umbrella by virtue of their status: cooperatives, mutual societies, associations and foundations;
  • ESUS-certified companies (entreprise solidaire d’utilité sociale) that meet the above criteria.

Not all SSE structures are for-profit organizations.

Find out more about the different types of structure on the BPI France website.

Without going into the details of all types of structures, we’ll concentrate here on two examples.

The mutual company (or mutual 34 ) is, under French law, “a non-profit legal entity governed by private law”, registered with the Registre national des mutuelles and subject to the provisions of the Mutual Societies Code . It pays no dividends, and all profits are invested for the benefit of its members.

The purpose of mutuals is to cover risks (health, various types of insurance). Members are the mutual’s customers. Based on the principle of one member, one vote, they elect delegates who, meeting at a general meeting, decide on the terms and conditions of the contract. 35 They in turn elect the members of the Board of Directors (who are also members of the mutual). The Board has specific supervisory prerogatives (see the Mutual Code for details), including the right to appoint the operational manager. As you can see, members play the same role here as shareholders in a company. It should be noted, however, that sovereign power is by construction very diluted, due to the principle of one member, one vote.

Cooperatives

The legal basis for all cooperatives is set by the 1947 law on the status of cooperation, which defines a cooperative as “a company formed by several people voluntarily united to meet their economic or social needs through their joint efforts and the establishment of the necessary means”. (Art. 1)

Each member has one vote at the Annual General Meeting, and profits must be reinvested in the cooperative as a priority. Surpluses may, however, be paid out to members, under conditions defined by the laws specific to each type of cooperative.

There are several main types of cooperatives

2020 panorama of cooperative businesses

types-of-cooperatives

Source Panorama 2020 des familles cooperatives, Coop FR

Not all cooperatives have the same legal form: for example, SCOPs and SCICs take the form of limited companies or SARLs, while agricultural cooperatives “form a special category of companies, distinct from civil companies and commercial companies” (see art. L521-1 of the French Rural and Maritime Fishing Code).

Finally, it’s worth noting that cooperatives bring together structures with a wide variety of purposes, some of which raise the question of their social utility (if not in their purpose, at least in their implementation). Crédit Agricole, for example, is a cooperative bank. 36 . It is also one of France’s four systemic banks.

SCOP (Société coopérative et participative) governance

In a SCOP, employees are at the heart of governance. They must hold at least 51% of the share capital and 65% of the voting rights, which are organized according to the “one person, one vote” principle. In this way, employees take the decisions that concern them most, notably by electing the SCOP’s managers and validating the major strategic orientations at the Annual General Meeting.

In addition, profits are obligatorily divided into three parts: the “company share” refers to the non-distributable reserves, which remain within the company; the “labor share” is redistributed to employees; and the “capital share” is paid out to associates (employees and non-employees) in the form of dividends;

In 2023, there were some 2,697 Scops in France, employing 60,000 people (70% of whom were associates) and generating sales of nearly 8 billion euros. Although they are generally small, they also include some very large, sometimes multinational companies, such as the Up group (formerly Chèque déjeuner). Scops also differ from one another in that some are highly militant, with a project for social transformation; others are primarily concerned with economic results.

Source Find out more: Anne-Catherine Wagner Cooperate. Scops and the collective interest factory CNRS éditions, 2022. The Confédération générale des Sociétés coopératives website.

Alternative models for “classic” commercial companies

Beyond the SSE, there are other forms of governance that ensure that, while profit is not rejected, its maximization is not the priority compass of management.

These alternatives are more far-reaching than simply displaying good corporate social responsibility and environmental practices, which remain subordinate to the imperative of maximum profitability. They involve alternative statutes or specific legal provisions that ensure that the company is not enslaved to financial performance alone, without abandoning the possibility of making profits and remunerating capital.

Shareholder foundations

Born in Northern Europe in the 1920s 37 the “shareholder foundation” model is a corporate ownership and governance model that responds to the desire of the shareholders (often the founders) of a commercial company to preserve the company’s project and protect it over the long term (against hostile takeovers, demands for returns, etc.).

In practical terms, shareholders give a foundation their shares (in part or in full) and the associated voting rights, in a proportion that can vary (it’s not necessarily one share = one vote) and whose number determines the foundation’s decision-making power, as a shareholder, over the company’s strategy.

Since it belongs to no one and cannot be bought out, the foundation protects the company’s capital and its project according to the mandate given to it. By definition, it is a shareholder of general interest, stable and long-term. Thanks to dividends or other donations, it can also carry out a philanthropic mission by supporting causes in the public interest.

The foundation shareholder is not in competition with other shareholders to demand higher returns; it can therefore demonstrate “temperance” in this area, especially as it has an objective interest in ensuring the long-term viability of the company, which is its sustainable source of financing.

Some foundations are able to do without dividends; others define dividend distribution rules designed to ensure the financing of the investee company’s development.

But “status does not make virtue”, and some shareholder foundations receive significant dividends. What’s more, having a foundation as a shareholder is obviously no guarantee of optimized environmental and social performance.

In France 38 Adam, Naos, Léa Nature, Laboratoires Pierre Fabre and Institut Mérieux, for example, are partly owned by shareholder foundations. In Europe, many other companies are in the same situation: Baur, BMW, Bosch, Carlsberg, Electrolux, Lego, Maersk, Migros, Rolex, Saab, SEB, Velux, Victorino, Carl Zeiss (one of the first)…

Mission-driven companies

Following the Notat-Sénard report 39 the Pacte Act of 2019 introduced the concept of a mission-driven company 40 along the lines of what already existed in the United States.

When a company wishes to obtain this status, it must define its raison d’être and social and environmental impact objectives in its articles of association. It must also set up a “mission committee” made up of various stakeholders responsible for monitoring and evaluating the execution of the mission (which is also monitored by an accredited independent third-party organization).

The mission-driven company is a step forward, as it enables managers to constructively oppose any pressure from shareholders for greater profitability if it contradicts the mission, and vice versa. In June 2024, there were some 1,650 mission-driven companies, mainly SMEs but also a few ETIs and a few large corporations.

It should be noted that the Pacte law also created a new form of shareholding via the “fonds de pérennité”, a hybrid structure, enjoying legal personality, allowing the holding and transfer of company shares (this is its primary purpose) and which can support causes of general interest.

The steward ownership movement

The concept of ” steward ownership ” was coined by the Purpose Foundation 41 to propose a “third way” for companies, between shareholder primacy and non-lucrativeness.

This model has the following objectives:

  • put the people really involved in the company back at the heart of governance;
  • align governance structures with a long-term vision, serving the company’s mission;
  • link voting rights to interests other than financial ones;
  • propose a new form of succession, which ensures a company’s longevity beyond its founder, while limiting the spread of inequalities through inheritance by democratizing capital.

This model is organized around two principles:

  • Self-governance: control of the company remains within the company, in the hands of people directly involved in its mission.
  • Profits serve purpose”: profits serve the mission and are reinvested in the company, its stakeholders or philanthropic initiatives. Limited “fair compensation” is offered to investors.

It can take the form of two families of devices:

  • shareholder structure: the shareholder foundation, the perpetual purpose trust
  • statutory mechanisms: creation of non-voting shares for investors (with preferential dividend), shares with double voting rights and/or without dividend granted to long-term stakeholders, golden share (share with veto right) entrusted to a third-party organization (foundation, State, NGO, etc.) to guarantee the pursuit of the mission, etc.

To date, around a hundred companies have been supported by the Purpose Foundation, including Bosch, Novo-Nordisk, Mozilla and Stapelstein. 42 … The Purpose Foundation cites several studies 43 which show a higher survival rate and better financial performance for foundation-owned companies in Denmark (a pioneer in the field of shareholder foundations).

However, it is still too early to draw any definitive conclusions as to whether these new models are leading to a better integration of planetary limits into decision-making; moreover, they are currently limited in number, by their “voluntary” nature and by certain legal difficulties (in France). They do, however, have the immense merit of showing that the quest for accounting profit (see our module on corporate accounting) and the general interest are not irreconcilable.

The focus on maximizing shareholder profit poses numerous ecological and social problems.

From the 1970s onwards, the idea that a company’s primary objective should be to maximize profits in order to remunerate its shareholders (see Misconception 2) was widely accepted. 44 This doctrine, which has the force of evidence for many, is reflected in reality by numerous negative impacts, or at least by a strong tension between the need for financial profitability and respect for environmental and/or social constraints.

Expected returns on financial capital and planetary limits

A company subject to high financial profitability requirements 45 is necessarily run with a high degree of pressure, whatever the human quality of the manager and his managerial talent.

Definition – What is the expected return on financial capital?

When a company is set up, the founder or founders contribute resources 46 to form the company’s share capital. This is divided into shares, allocated to the founders (henceforth referred to as shareholders) in proportion to their contribution. Ownership of these shares confers rights of participation in decisions taken by the company’s General Meeting, as well as financial rights (via the payment of dividends). Once issued, shares can be sold either through bilateral exchanges or publicly on organized markets (stock exchanges).

For shareholders, this capital is an investment that can generate income through the distribution of dividends when the company makes a profit, and also increase in value if the value of the shares rises (if they are sold, the owner realizes a capital gain). The return on capital is what it brings back to the shareholder in at least one of these two forms.

A company is listed on the stock market because it promises a return, usually a high one, to attract investors. Contrary to popular belief, this expected return does not necessarily translate into immediate financial gains (dividends) for the shareholder. The promise of high returns can be fulfilled by share valuations alone (which can result from a variety of factors, such as brand awareness, sales growth, etc.). This explains why the shares of companies like Amazon or Tesla have enjoyed high valuations even though the companies themselves were loss-making.

In the face of such demands, environmental and social constraints whose observance is not made strictly compulsory by the legislator generally take second place, as they are likely to weaken short-term profitability and hence the return on capital.47

Even where standards exist, managers may seek to circumvent them, whether by outsourcing or relocating part of their business to countries with lower social and environmental standards, or by fraud (as demonstrated, for example, by “dieselgate“).

This is not to say that all companies with high profitability requirements do nothing for the environment or society. First of all, certain activities with a positive impact on the environment can enjoy significant growth and high financial valuations. Secondly, consumer pressure can be a driving force. Health scandals, social disasters (such as the collapse of the Rana Plaza in 2013) or environmental disasters can thus prompt management to change, under pressure from consumers, but more often than not in a reactive rather than proactive approach. Finally, the anticipation of tensions over raw materials can lead managers to encourage sobriety of use or accelerate recycling, without preventing them from maintaining significant profits. 48

But these are clearly exceptions. The best proof of this is that, despite numerous declarations of intent, our economy, “driven” by large multinationals (whose power is excessive, see Essentiel 10), is still very (and far too) extractive and carbon-based.

Finally, the expected rate of return on capital is decisive for financing the ecological transition. Current rates of return in financial capitalism are widely recognized as excessive. They are generally much higher than those that most ecological investment projects can deliver. However, this is not inevitable: on the one hand, these rates are the lowest in economic history; on the other, there are companies that are not subject to such pressure. The structures of the social and solidarity-based economy, the purpose-economy movement and steward ownership, which we presented in Essentiel 4 on the various forms of corporate governance, aim precisely to escape this “tyranny of return”.

A very narrow conception of the value created by the company

In reaction to the growing influence of the theory of maximizing shareholder value, numerous works have been developed to denounce the decline since the 1980s in the share of labor compensation in value added in the United States and Europe. 49 and to assert the importance of sharing value between shareholders and employees. These debates are regularly fuelled by scandals concerning dividends paid out by major corporations and share buy-backs.

What is added value?

In business accounting, added value is sales minus intermediate consumption (purchases of goods and services required for production). It is a management indicator that measures the financial value generated by the company once it has paid all its suppliers and service providers. It is divided between employee remuneration, taxes, investments and return on capital (debt and dividends).

At the macroeconomic level, GDP is made up of the sum of value added generated by all public and private economic players. This value added is also broken down into employee remuneration, capital remuneration, investment and public taxes.

Source To find out more, see our modules on corporate accounting and GDP, growth and planetary limits.

The subject of value sharing needs to be broadened beyond the mere question of capital and labor. Promoters of shareholder value identify the “value created by the company” with profit, which is very restrictive. It is much more sales that represent this value, the one for which customers pay.

Seen in this light, it’s clear that value is shared by all stakeholders: suppliers and service providers, employees, the public purse via taxes and social security contributions, shareholders via dividends, bankers where applicable, and finally the company itself (investments, development).

Each of these stakeholders receives “its share” according to either regulations (taxation, regulated professions, monetary policy), or the “market” (more or less regulated, more or less oligopolistic) and the resulting balance of power (between workers, managers and shareholders, between principals and suppliers, etc.). This is one of the reasons why the company is a source of both cooperation and conflict (see Essential 3): it is thanks to the coordinated action made possible by the company that each party “receives” its share, the share of each being limited by that of the others.

To reason in a binary way, by opposing labor and capital, is to forget all the other stakeholders who also suffer from the doctrine of shareholder maximization: suppliers and service providers, whose prices will be demanded as low as possible, and public authorities, through pressure to reduce taxes on companies, or to lower the standards imposed on companies to limit their nuisances.

Finally, while financial value is today’s dominant metric, it is only one dimension of a company’s overall capital and of value as such: companies have varying degrees of social utility (the latter sometimes being zero, or even negative); they often have negative impacts on the environment (see Essential 9); certain stakeholders may prefer a non-financial reward (e.g. reduced working hours, training, annualized contract for a supplier…) to an increase, etc.

Pay differentials and inequality

The level of executive compensation at major corporations is regularly in the news. Increases in this area are mainly the consequence of the predominance of the shareholder value doctrine, which has led to the interests of executives being aligned with those of shareholders, notably through remuneration (variable portion, bonuses, stock options, etc. seeMisconception 2).

This issue is not neutral in terms of social cohesion: when an executive is paid tens of millions of euros while his company is sold to the highest bidder 50 or engages in massive cost-cutting (even laying off staff or relocating), this sends out signals that are difficult for many citizens to bear.

It’s even more difficult if, at the same time, the government develops a rhetoric on the efforts to be made in terms of social rights such as pensions, unemployment or more generally to reduce public spending.

How are salaries set?

As a general rule, companies set salaries by comparison with practices observed for similar positions in comparable companies (size, business sector, financial performance, etc.). They may, of course, do a little better or a little worse, depending on the urgency of the recruitment and the more or less strategic nature of their needs for the positions in question. As a first approximation, however, it can be said that “the law of the market” applies to everyone. It will be difficult for an employee or a company to be paid a salary that is permanently very different from the market average.

The labor “market” does not necessarily remunerate work according to its “social value”.

The Covid crisis clearly showed that essential jobs were poorly paid and poorly recognized. Conversely, anthropologist David Graeber has highlighted the existence of bullshit jobs“. 51 jobs that have no meaning, even for the employees themselves, even though they are well-paid and well-recognized. The exorbitant salaries of soccer or movie stars are sometimes “justified” by the “law of the market”, which cares neither for morality nor for consistency between the social value of the service rendered and remuneration. This is a matter for public intervention, as social cohesion is clearly at stake in the growth of unfounded pay disparities.

Wages are not based on labor productivity 52 contrary to what most economists believe. Productivity is generally impossible to measure, except in very specific and limited cases. And it is never completely individualizable: an employee’s contribution depends on the organization, the equipment at his disposal and his colleagues.

Salary may not be the only component of an employee’s remuneration, which may also include :

  • the distribution of a portion of profits to employees: in France, this is the case with statutory profit-sharing for companies of a certain size, or with profit-sharing agreements.
  • an annual bonus linked more or less objectively to performance.
  • a stake in the company’s capital via a number of mechanisms (stock options, bonus share allocations, share subscription warrants, etc.). 53
  • benefits in kind: luncheon vouchers, company-paid health insurance, company car or housing, etc.

In addition, executives may be awarded exceptional supplements (a welcome bonus, a severance bonus, a “top-hat pension”, etc.).

The equity ratio: the transparent way to limit pay disparities

One of the main ways in which governments have so far sought to influence pay differentials is through transparency: encouraging self-regulation by players by making data public.

Equity ratio compares total compensation 54 of the principal executive(s) to the average compensation of full-time employees in the company. For example, if this ratio is 100 in a company, this means that the CEO earns 100 times more than the average compensation of his employees.

Introduced since 2018 in the United States and the United Kingdom, it was introduced in European Union countries following the SRD II directive (2017). This was transposed in France by the Pacte law of 2019 55 which made it mandatory for listed companies to publish this ratio. 56

The equity ratio in the United States

In the United States, the equity ratio rose from 20 in 1965 to over 300 (or even 400) in the 2000s, before “falling back” to around 200 after the financial crisis.

CEO Pay in 2012 Was Extraordinarily High Relative to Typical Workers and Other High Earners – Economic Policy Institute (2013)

The equity ratio in Europe and France

Ratio of CEO compensation to average salary

The ratio of CEO total compensation to average salary in 350 listed companies in 11 European countries in 2015 was 96.

ratio-equite-europe

Source Executive compensation in Europe: Realized gains from stock-based pay – INET (2018)

This article was subsequently published in a revised version in Review of International Political Economy: Patricia Kotnik, Mustafa Erdem Sakinç, Executive compensation in Europe: realized gains from stock-based pay, 2022.

In France, within the CAC 40, the ratio between the average income of CEOs (5 million euros) and the average compensation of their employees was 53 (72 in relation to median compensation) in 2019. This figure conceals major differences from one company to the next: for example, at Dassault Systèmes and Sanofi, the equity ratio was 268 and 107 respectively.

ratio-equite-france

Source Rémunération des dirigeants : la transparence ne fait pas tout, Mohamed Khenissi, Vanessa Serret, The Conversation (27/07/2020).

Many critics have questioned the value of this ratio.57

  • Statistics are particularly sensitive to changes in CEO income alone. Much more volatile than average salaries, it is often the primary explanation for changes in equity ratios.
  • As with any indicator, this ratio is open to interpretation. For example, in France, as the law does not specify a perimeter, it is possible to calculate the equity ratio on the basis of the parent company alone, which is often a holding company with a few dozen employees, which leads to an underestimation of the ratio compared with what it would be if the entire group were taken into account. Thus, based on declarations alone, the 2024 edition of the CSR Criteria and Remuneration study evaluates the equity ratio at 73 in 2023 for CAC 40 companies. “Calculations by the voting consultancy Proxinvest Glass Lewis give different results: an average ratio of 130 in favor of CAC 40 executives for the year 2022.”” 58
  • The equity ratio is limited to a comparison between the remuneration of key executives (or even the CEO alone) and average earnings. It would be far more interesting to understand the distribution of income in greater detail, in particular the gaps between the first decile or percentile (depending on the number of employees) and the other deciles within the company, as is the case with any measure of inequality.
Finally, and most importantly, transparency and goodwill are not enough to achieve the goal of limiting income disparities.

Several years after its introduction in France, the equity ratio has had no tangible effect on pay differentials. Very few investors have used it as a shareholder governance tool, and its impact on the general public has been weak. 58

Only voluntary action by public authorities can have a real impact, as proposed by Gaël Giraud and Cécile Renouard(who suggest establishing a ratio of 12 between maximum and minimum wages).

This can be achieved by capping compensation. In France, since 2012 in public companies the remuneration of executives appointed by the Minister of the Economy (i.e. corporate officers and in particular the MD or CEO) may not exceed a ceiling set at 450,000 euros. 60

Income tax can also be used. In the wake of the Second World War, the final income tax bracket in the United States reached record levels, to some extent limiting the appeal of very high salaries: on the eve of Ronald Reagan’s arrival in power (1981), the tax rate for a single person was 70% on the income bracket above $460,000. 61

How is a company financed?

A company is a living organism that is born, changes and can disappear. At every stage of its existence, the question of financing is vital.

Created by its founders, it lives and develops according to its environment, its stakeholders and the decisions taken by its managers. It can evolve significantly, either organically by developing its activity (through hiring, purchasing new equipment, etc.), or by acquiring (or merging with) other companies, or by partial or total divestment of some of its activities. It can also die, if it is no longer profitable or if the manager cannot find a buyer. Another possible cause is a lack of cash flow, i.e. money available for the company to meet its financial commitments (payment of supplier invoices, taxes, salaries, bank charges, etc.). The company then finds itself in a situation of “cessation of payments“), which is a cause of bankruptcy that can lead to the company’s dissolution.

In this section, we’ll look at what a company’s financing needs are, how they can be met, and what impact they have on corporate governance and strategy.

Why do companies need financing?

A general distinction is made between :

  • long-term requirements to finance the investments needed to create and develop the company;
  • short-term requirements to finance the operating cycle.
Financing creation and investment: long-term needs

All business start-ups involve investments, which can be substantial if the company is highly capital-intensive (e.g.: development of industrial activities, drug development, etc.) or very limited (e.g.: self-employed consultant who only needs a computer). Initial investments can also be used to finance initial inventories.

Then, over the course of the company’s life, new investments may be needed to purchase new machinery, expand into other regions or internationally, design new products, develop IT platforms and so on.

Definition – What is a highly capital-intensive company?

This refers to a company that uses a lot of productive capital to generate sales: machines, buildings, purchase of patents, goodwill, research and development, database creation, etc. By extension, this expression also refers to the need for financial resources (self-financing, capital provided by shareholders, debt, subsidies, etc.) to finance this productive capital. By extension, this expression also refers to the need for financial resources (self-financing, capital provided by shareholders, debt, subsidies) to finance this productive capital.

Here we find the ambiguity of the word capital:

  • Productive capital” is on the assets side of the balance sheet 62 (fixed assets).
  • The company’s “share capital”, located on the liabilities side of the balance sheet, refers to the resources contributed by shareholders and takes the form of financial securities (shares).
  • In the world of finance, “capital” can also refer to a company’s financial resources in the broadest sense.

Investing means betting on the future: the entrepreneur anticipates that the profits from future sales generated by investments will pay back their cost over the years.

This is why, when recorded in the accounts, investments are amortized over several years (their cost is spread over several years, rather than being counted in full in the first year). On the other hand, the company must, of course, disburse all sums due at the time the investment is made (e.g.: pay suppliers of machinery or construction companies constructing buildings, etc.).

Appropriate financing is therefore required. This can take several forms, as detailed in sections 6.2 to 6.4.

Understanding the difference between accounting records and cash flows

  • A company’s profit and loss statement is an accounting document that traces the annual flow of expenses (purchases, salaries, taxes and social security contributions, depreciation of investments, etc.) and income (sales of goods and services, subsidies, financial income, etc.). The balance (called “income”) is used to determine whether the company made a loss or a profit during the year.
  • The cash flow statement shows “money movements” in real time.
  • There may be significant timing differences between the accounting entry and the actual receipt (or disbursement).
  • One example is the depreciation of the investments described above. The following is an example of the time lag between the recording of an invoice and the actual disbursement during the production cycle.
Financing the operating cycle: short-term needs

Once investments have been made and any initial stock financed, the company enters the operating cycle.

On the expenditure side, it pays its employees’ salaries, purchases and other supplies, any financial expenses, taxes and social security contributions.

On the revenue side, the company receives income from sales, subsidies or financial income (if it has holdings in other companies, for example).

In the short term, the company’s main source of financing is sales.

However, even if the company has a positive accounting result, it may be short of cash and have difficulty meeting its financial commitments. In practice, payment and collection may be deferred from the time the invoice is issued. For example, many SMEs supplying large groups or government bodies are paid several months after delivery, whereas they cannot defer payment to their employees.

On the other hand, supermarket companies collect cash from their customers and pay their suppliers within two months (in theory). 63 They are therefore partly financed by their operating cycle. 64

Depending on the situation, companies may have a greater or lesser need for working capital (WCR), i.e. cash on hand to meet their obligations or renew their inventories until they have sold their production and/or received payment. In the retail sector, working capital is negative (since consumers buy goods that distributors have not yet paid for), whereas for some SMEs or farmers, it can be very high.

This WCR can be financed by retained earnings from previous years (self-financing). It can also be financed by a bank loan (backed, for example, by the discounting of bills of exchange, or by techniques such as factoring). Basically, the company brings an invoice to the bank or other financial institution, which grants a loan for the amount (with interest) until the invoice is paid by the customer.

The different types of long-term financing

Companies have a number of sources 65 of long-term financing:

  • self-financing occurs when management decides (with shareholder approval) to reinvest the company’s profits in its development;
  • capital and advances from associates ;
  • Borrowing: via bank loans or on the financial markets;
  • donations”, which most often take the form of public aid (subsidies, repayable advances, tax credits, etc.). This point is developed inEssentiel 7.

The relative share of these sources of financing differs from country to country and from period to period. Recourse to bank loans is much greater in Europe than in the United States. The use of capital markets has grown worldwide over the past 20 years. It also depends on company size: capital markets, for example, are difficult to access for SMEs (at least in Europe).

These sources of financing can come from different types of players: financial institutions, of course (banking or non-banking), but also the State (and more generally public players), individuals, or other companies (particularly in the case of intra-group credit). There is not necessarily a correspondence between a type of funder and a type of financing. For example, public bodies can grant loans, make equity investments or provide subsidies. Another example is crowdfunding platforms, which collect a multitude of small contributions to finance a specific project run by a company (or an association or individual). Funding can take the form of a donation, a loan, or an equity stake. 66

These various sources do not have the same counterparts in terms of governance.

  • Self-financing is the least restrictive source of financing, except for the fact that you need to make enough profit to be able to make investments, which is difficult when needs are high.
  • Capital financing gives shareholders rights: holding the majority of the capital (in the sense of the voting rights associated with the shares) gives management power.
  • Loans do not give management powers but may be conditional on guarantees and/or covenants. 67 which can give lenders a powerful influence.
  • Public aid may be subject to conditions.

Finally, the risks taken by financiers are not the same. When liquidation (i.e. the “death” of a company) is decided, the assets (buildings, machinery, patents, etc.) are sold off, and the proceeds used to repay creditors in a clearly defined order:

  • Certain claims by company employees are always paid first. The same applies to court fees, court clerk’s fees and legal expenses.
  • Next come tax and social security creditors.
  • Then there are the other preferred creditors, those who benefit from a “security” granted by the company (for example, a bank that has granted a loan and benefits from a mortgage on the business premises).
  • Lastly, there are the so-called “unsecured” creditors, i.e. those who do not benefit from any lien, and who are often numerous.

In most cases, capital is not recovered by shareholders, as the proceeds from the sale of assets do not cover all liabilities.

Capital financing

The founder(s) of a company contribute resources to build up the company’s share capital. These are in the form of shares, i.e. financial securities which can then be sold on organized markets (stock exchanges) or through bilateral exchanges. Over the course of the company’s life, management may decide to ask existing shareholders to provide new financing, or to try to find new capital investors, in which case new shares are issued.

These shares give their holders the power to participate in strategic decisions affecting the company. This applies in particular to the allocation of profits (if any), which shareholders may decide to distribute to themselves (in the form of dividends).

What are the reasons for remunerating capital contributions?

Capitalism has developed for many reasons, one of which is the remuneration of financial capital. Industrial and related companies 68 require a great deal of financial capital. This capital is provided directly or indirectly by savers, who demand a return in return, for at least three reasons:

  • this contribution is accompanied by the deprivation of immediate enjoyment of the capital in question,
  • the capital contribution is riskier than a loan (if the latter is granted after serious analysis) and therefore gives rise to a demand for remuneration incorporating a “risk premium” compared with a loan.
  • this contribution is generally 69 relatively illiquid (it is not possible to recover one’s contribution at any time). Uncertainty as to the possible date for regaining enjoyment of the capital has a cost for the contributor.

While the remuneration of capital is legitimate, excesses in this area are highly problematic, both for the company’s long-term viability and for ecological and social reasons (seeEssential 5).

We present below the three main forms of capital contribution (family capital, private equity and the stock market), bearing in mind that there are, of course, hybrid cases (one part of the capital being held on the stock market or by a financier and the other being family-owned, for example).

Family capital

In many companies, the first source of capital often comes from the founder’s own savings, and possibly from family and friends. This is generally the case for small start-ups, but is not limited to very large groups. 70 have managed to maintain almost exclusive family control of capital.

In theory, family capital should be concerned above all with the success of the founder(s)’ project, as well as the long-term survival and successful transfer of the company. This does not, of course, mean pursuing profitability objectives, which are necessary to guarantee control of the company and protect against economic crises and, more generally, the vagaries of corporate life. 71 . However, in theory, these long-term “values” should take priority over maximizing short-term financial returns.

In reality, family capitalism can be frighteningly predatory, as shown by the case of the well-known billionaires 72 . And it is not always a model of transparency or managerial quality. According to a study published by Family Capital in 2021, listed family businesses are rated lower than non-family-owned listed companies by the ESG risk assessment department 73 department of PwC Luxembourg. While this data, like all ESG rating data, must of course be treated with caution, as it depends on the methodology used, it is nonetheless interesting for comparative purposes, particularly in terms of transparency (the absence of public data translates into poor ratings).

There’s an apparent paradox here, as one might think that a family business should think more about its “sustainability” in the physical and financial sense. This is sometimes the case… but not always. As long as there is no immediate upstream risk, or obvious loss of market share, the profit motive remains the rule (family or not)…

Private equity funds

Investment funds provide financing by acquiring stakes in unlisted companies. 74 for a fixed term (rarely more than 10 years).

Made up of a team of investment professionals, they generally specialize in a particular sector (e.g. real estate) or phase of a company’s life.

The different segments of private equity

  • Venture capital finances young companies with high financing requirements (e.g. high-tech sectors requiring a lot of R&D). Also included in this segment are business angels, individuals who invest part of their wealth in young companies, while also providing advice to management.
  • development capital targets more mature companies, which need capital to continue growing.
  • LBO funds (or buyout funds) invest in business transfers (large groups divesting one of their subsidiaries, family businesses with succession problems, companies delisted from the stock market).
  • turnaround capital funds buy out companies in difficulty.

Private equity players invest resources entrusted to them by other financial institutions (particularly, but not exclusively, those that collect public savings, such as insurance companies, pension funds, banks, etc.). Their need for “visibility” on the financial situation of the companies in which they invest is important, as they report regularly to the institutions that have entrusted them with the funds. They expect company management to “deliver” what it has promised, particularly in terms of financial returns.

The stock market

To raise additional capital, a company’s management may decide to list all or part of its capital on a stock exchange, such as Euronext, the main stock market in the euro zone, or the New York Stock Exchange or Nasdaq in the United States.

The shares can then be traded freely between players on the stock market’s so-called “secondary market” (see box).

Asset managers (who invest the funds collected directly from savers or from other financial institutions such as insurance companies, banks, sovereign wealth funds, etc.) are the most powerful, but there are also banks and insurance companies (which invest the money collected via savings books or life insurance, for example), hedge funds, sovereign wealth funds, etc., all of which are involved in the stock market.) are the most powerful, but there are also banks and insurance companies (which invest the money collected via savings books or life insurance, for example), hedge funds, sovereign wealth funds, holders of large fortunes and small savers who invest their assets directly (via brokers or online banking).

Definition – Primary and secondary markets

Stock exchanges are organized markets for public offerings. They are made up of two segments, each with its own distinct functions.

  • The primary market (the “new” market) enables a company to obtain new financing. This is when the company floats all or part of its capital on the stock market, or when it carries out a capital increase.
  • The secondary market (the “second-hand” market) enables financial players to exchange shares already in circulation. The aim is no longer to provide the company with financing, but to ensure the liquidity of its shares, i.e. that those who buy them can easily resell them.

The primary market accounts for only a small proportion of transactions. In 2006, for example, “on Euronext, the Paris-based stock exchange, IPOs and capital increases accounted for 79 billion euros, while total share sales amounted to 2,345 billion euros”. 75

Furthermore, in a study published in 2021, economist Catherine Lubochinsky drew a worrying conclusion about this form of corporate financing: “The stock markets have not been financing, in net flows (i.e. IPOs and capital increases minus share buy-backs), the American and European economies for some twenty years now.”“” 76

Stock market players are demanding both in terms of liquidity (being able to sell their shares at any time) and financial return.

These requirements place severe constraints on managers, who can be dismissed and replaced by more “efficient” managers if they fail to perform to expectations.

This is particularly the case when a company is controlled by a majority block (one or a few financial players hold the majority of shares, the remainder being distributed in a diffuse manner) primarily focused on short-term performance. It should be noted that, individually, “diffuse” minority shareholders have very little power. 77 on the life of the company. Only those with a relative majority have any power, as decisions at the Annual General Meeting (including the appointment of the Chairman of the Board of Directors or the Management Board) are generally taken on a “one share, one vote” basis. 78

In the case of a company whose capital is not “controlled”, i.e. whose shareholding is very diffuse (shares are held by a multitude of unconnected players), the company’s management may have more room for manoeuvre. It does, however, expose itself to the risk of a “hostile takeover”. If the share price is too low in relation to its potential (which would be achieved by a “tougher” management team), predatory shareholders may take advantage of the situation to buy up the shares of diffuse shareholders on a massive scale, via a hostile takeover bid (known as a “raid”). If they manage to take control of the company in this way, they then have the power to try to improve the company’s short-term profitability, in order to make a significant capital gain from the eventual resale of their shares. This improvement in the company’s profitability is often achieved by cutting costs (labor, R&D, investment) or selling off assets, which means sacrificing the company’s long-term viability.

Hedge funds specialize in this type of operation. The authors of a study published in 2020 79 analyzed the impact of 1,234 campaigns carried out by hedge funds between 2000 and 2016. According to this work, while the immediate performance in terms of market value and profitability is indeed there in the short term, the negative long-term impacts are negative. In the 5 years following a “raid”, 4% to 8% of jobs have been destroyed, R&D has been weakened, consideration of social and environmental responsibility issues has collapsed, and the company perishes, with a drop in share value of up to 10%.

Debt can take two main forms

Bank credit

Lending bankers have two objectives: to be repaid the amount of the loan and to collect the interest on that loan. They do not seek to (and are not competent to) involve themselves in the management of the company to which they lend. They are even very careful to avoid any legal risk in this respect: if they were suspected of interference, they could be considered as de facto liable and ordered to make good any liabilities in the event of cash flow difficulties.

Consequently, bank loans are not accompanied by decision-making powers. They are, however :

  • designed to limit the risk of non-repayment (hence the famous expression “you only lend to the rich”);
  • combined with measures to limit risk in the event of default by the debtor: guarantees or covenants 67 obliging debtors to provide regular economic information on their situation, to enable the banker to anticipate the onset of insolvency.
Issuing debt securities (or bonds) on the financial markets

Bond issues are subject to numerous legal and tax constraints, and are often inaccessible to small businesses.

How does a bond issue work? Simplified explanation

Let’s imagine that the TOE company needs two million euros. It can ask its banker for a loan, or sell its debt to various investors (in particular asset managers) in the form of financial securities called debt securities, for example 200 securities of €10,000.

These securities have three characteristics:

> the amount lent, called the nominal or principal amount (here €10,000),

> the maturity of the loan (in one, two, three … ten years).

> the interest rate (e.g. 2%), which is the borrower’s remuneration to the creditor.

Unlike a bank loan, the issuer of a debt security pays only the interest each year. The principal is repaid when the bond reaches maturity.

As with equities, the company receives financing when the securities are issued, i.e. when the first buyers are found. These securities can then be traded on the bond market, raising or lowering their market value according to the level of demand for the security.

Naturally, the company wants to obtain loans at the lowest possible cost. But the level of the interest rate depends on several factors:

  • The macro-economic environment: the general level of interest rates in the economy, which is influenced by the central bank’s monetary policy (more information in our module on money). Central banks’ highly accommodating monetary policy over the past decade has had a global impact in keeping interest rates low for all players.
  • The specific situation of the company and the lenders’ perception of the risks involved (financial situation of the company, sector of activity, competitive positioning). As in the case of bank loans, this implies considerable financial reporting effort (often within a strict framework), so that bond investors can decide whether or not to buy the bond.
  • The situation of debt securities already issued by the company: when their market value is higher than their face value (reflecting strong demand), this means that the company can issue new bonds at a lower rate than before. And vice versa.

Bankers and lenders in general have a strong influence on companies, starting with the fact that they impose de facto reporting and performance formats as a condition of accepting their loan or stock purchase.

Companies pay taxes and receive public funding

The debate on corporate taxation often boils down to a binary confrontation between those who believe that companies should be taxed more (particularly the largest), and those who believe that any form of taxation is detrimental to economic activity. Here, we attempt to clarify the terms of the debate, and provide some orders of magnitude.

Some definitions: compulsory levies, taxes, social security contributions

Compulsory levies (on companies and households) are all taxes and social contributions received by public administrations (APU) without any direct and immediate counterpart. 81

Taxes and other contributions are payments made by individuals and legal entities, according to their ability to pay, to public authorities, without any specific consideration, in order to cover public expenditure and achieve economic and social objectives set by public authorities.

Social security contributionsare payments made to public authorities for a specific purpose (social protection), giving entitlement to social benefits.

There are several economic reasons why companies pay taxes and social security contributions: contribution to public financing and environmental taxation.

On the one hand, they use infrastructure to produce goods and services 82 and benefit, directly or indirectly, from public services and social protection 83 provided by the state. It is therefore rational for them to participate in their financing and to include them in their accounts, in the same way as other goods and services used for production.

On the other hand, taxation (and public subsidies) can be economic policy tools for the State, providing signals to guide behavior and investment. This is particularly true of ecological taxation.

Companies use natural resources and have negative impacts on nature, for which they pay nothing. Raising the cost of natural resource extraction and environmental pollution (whether through taxation or quota markets) is a lever for reducing these impacts.

It can also help make it economically viable to clean up and “repair” the damage done to nature. Provided we use price as a complementary tool to others (regulation, prohibition, budget, monetary and prudential policy), and without making it the sole solution to environmental problems. We discuss this subject in detail in the fact sheet Should we put a price on nature?

This internalization 84 of negative impacts in the company’s costs has several positive effects:

  • Customers pay more for goods or services that have a negative impact on nature: this is the “truth” of pricing. However, this requires all companies to be subject to the same type of taxation. Otherwise, the effect is counter-productive: consumers could choose products from a company that pollutes more than others, simply because it is not subject to the same environmental mechanisms (and therefore supplies cheaper products). This is the problem posed by imports from countries not subject to taxes or quota markets such as those in force in the European Union.
  • Companies offering solutions can promote the benefits (in terms of reduced ecotaxes) to their prospects and customers.

In Europe, environmental taxes are relatively low. The European Commission estimates them at 55 billion euros in France, or 2% of GDP and 4.5% of total compulsory taxes. 85 The largest share comes from energy taxes. We will not deal here with the CO2 quota mechanism (see forthcoming fact sheet).

The company passes on its costs and taxes to its customers

The company passes on all its costs, including taxes, in its selling prices. By construction, sales (or, more strictly, total revenues) are equal to total expenses plus profit.

In the final analysis, therefore, it is the customers (and, at the end of the chain, the consumers) who, through their purchases, “pay” the company’s taxes, as well as all its other expenses and profits. If a company manages to make a profit, it’s because its selling prices (including compulsory levies) are deemed acceptable by its customers.

This simple observation does not mean, of course, that the level of compulsory taxation has no impact. It’s obvious that raising taxes too high can harm companies’ profitability, by increasing their costs too much, and thus the prices their customers are willing to accept. This is particularly the case when they are competing with other companies that do not have the same level of taxation.

What’s more, a change in taxation can be complex when it is introduced.

Let’s imagine that one of the production taxes increases:

  • some companies decide to pass on this increase to customers by raising their selling prices, with the risk of reducing sales.
  • others, unable to pass on the increase to customers (usually for competitive or regulatory reasons), see their profits fall.
  • for still others, a mix of the two above will be implemented.

In the case of a tax cut, all three cases are equally applicable, so it’s not clear whether such a cut would benefit consumers or, on the contrary, only shareholders…

So it’s wrong to generalize that taxes on business are paid by businesses, not households; and equally wrong to deny any impact of a change in tax structure on business performance.

How much tax is levied on companies and how much public support do they receive?

Compulsory levies on companies include social security contributions, production taxes, taxes on profits and taxes on products (but not VAT, for which companies are collectors on behalf of the Treasury, and which are not included in their cost price or profit and loss account).

It’s not easy to estimate the total amount. Indeed, while some data is available, not all of it is. We’re going to clarify these points here.

Overview of compulsory taxes levied on businesses and public subsidies

In 2023, in France, the contribution of non-financial corporations (NFCs) to compulsory taxes amounted to 345 billion euros, or 27% of total OP (and 12% of GDP). Subsidies paid by public authorities to NFCs amounted to 69 billion euros in the same year.

Since the late 1970s, the tax burden on non-financial companies has fluctuated between 12 and 13% of GDP.

Compulsory levies on non-financial companies

Source Les comptes de la Nation 2023 (tables: 7.101 on NFC accounts; 1.106 for GDP and 3.217 on main taxes by category).

Comments :

– The scope used here is that of non-financial companies. It therefore differs from the scope of INSEE’s structural business statistics (see Essentiel 1). In particular, it does not include sole proprietorships, as not all statistics are available on a long-term basis (particularly those relating to income tax).

– Social security contributions paid by employers to the public treasury are actually slightly lower than those presented here. The figures available in the national accounts mix them up with contributions to voluntary social insurance schemes (pension funds), which are not part of compulsory deductions. The latter have been rising steadily since the 2010s. 86

– As we shall see below, other compulsory levies (taxes on products, employee social security contributions) are included in the accounts of NFCs, but the statistics available do not allow us to highlight them.

Taxes on production

These taxes are linked to the production activity itself, and are each based on one of the following three tax bases: wages and salaries, property and productive capital (company assets) or various intermediate management balances (sales, added value). The main production taxes are those on land and value added.

For the company, these taxes represent production costs 87 which are therefore factored into the selling price. A downward variation can therefore result in higher margins and/or lower selling prices. The balance between these two effects depends on many factors, starting with the intensity of competition.

More on production taxes in section 7.4.

Corporate income tax

Unlike production taxes, the various income taxes do not affect a company’s costs, but only its earnings. They therefore have no direct impact on competitiveness. They can, however, have an indirect effect, by reducing the company’s relative capacity to build up reserves, since they reduce profits, which can either be distributed to shareholders in the form of dividends, or reinjected into the company in the form of reserves. From this point of view, it would be appropriate to devise a tax system that favours the creation of reserves over the distribution of dividends.

The main tax in this category is corporate income tax (IS).

It is sometimes said that corporate income tax is a tax on company capital or shareholder income. This is incorrect. Corporate income tax is a tax on a company’s profits, not on its capital, and certainly not on its shareholders (who personally pay tax on the income they derive from the company when they pay themselves dividends, or when they realize a capital gain by selling their shares).

The corporate income tax rate was recently lowered significantly to bring it into line with the international average. As economist Olivier Passet explains, 88 this reduction has not, however, been reflected in tax revenues. In fact, the reduction in production taxes and upstream social security contributions has led to an increase in margins, and thus a broadening of the corporate income tax base.

More details on SI in section 7.4.

Taxes on products

These are taxes paid per unit of goods and services produced or traded. For the most part, these are indirect taxes. 89 The most important of these is value-added tax (VAT), which has no impact on company accounts (see box).
Other taxes on products, on the other hand, are paid by companies (and households) at the time of purchase. This is the case, for example, with energy taxes (fuel, gas, electricity) and taxes on real estate transactions (purchase of real estate). Other taxes on products specifically target certain businesses: the general tax on polluting activities, the tax on digital services and telecommunications. 90

VAT is not a burden on (most) companies’ accounts

VAT is generally “transparent” for most companies 91 which essentially play the role of “collector” on behalf of the Treasury. In practical terms, a company subject to VAT invoices the products and services it sells, applying the appropriate VAT rate to the amount before tax (i.e., the customer pays the total including VAT). When the company makes purchases, it pays the amount including VAT. At the end of the fiscal year, the VAT amounts collected on sales and paid on purchases must equalize. If the difference is positive (i.e., the company has invoiced more VAT than it has collected), it is paid to the Treasury. If the difference is negative, the Treasury reimburses the company.

International trade excludes VAT. All other things being equal, replacing compulsory levies on a company’s production costs with VAT is favorable to the international competitiveness of companies (by reducing their sales prices excluding VAT) and weighs relatively more heavily on imported goods and services. This is the advantage of the mechanism known as social VAT.

Social security contributions

Companies pay social security contributions that contribute to the various pillars of social security: sickness (which also covers maternity, disability and death), unemployment, industrial accidents and occupational diseases, family and old age. 92

Employers’ contributions are paid by companies (not by the employer…), as are employees’ contributions. Both are therefore integrated into their production costs and contribute to the employee’s “social security cover”. The rate of contributions varies according to salary level (for example, it is very low at the minimum wage). 93

The main difference between employee and employer contributions is that the former are deducted from the employee’s gross salary. As a result, if the government decides to reduce employee contributions, this normally results in an increase in the net salary paid to the employee, with no impact on the company’s accounts. On the other hand, a reduction in employer contributions results in lower costs for the company, with no immediate impact on the employee. 94

From the 1990s onwards, part of the social security contributions were gradually replaced by taxes on income (wages and salaries, but also income from assets). These included the Contribution Sociale Généralisée(CSG)and the Contribution pour le Réimbursement de la Dette Sociale (CRDS), which replaced some of the employee contributions on pay slips.

Since 2019, the reduction in employers’ social security contributions following the transformation of the Employment Competitiveness Tax Credit (CICE) into a permanent reduction in charges has been clearly perceptible.

Public assistance

While companies pay taxes and social security contributions, they also benefit from various forms of budgetary aid (mainly subsidies and investment grants). These amounted to 69 billion euros in 2023. 95

A report by the Institut de Recherches Économiques et Sociales 96 published in 2022, estimated public aid to businesses at 157 billion euros in 2019, including not only budgetary aid but also “tax expenditure” (sometimes called tax niches, which are mechanisms that allow tax reductions, including tax credits) and socio-fiscal reductions (exemptions from employers’ social security contributions).

Focus on direct taxes

Direct taxes on businesses include two of the categories mentioned above: taxes on production (see section 7.3.2) and taxes on business results (see section 7.3.3).

By 2022, their total amounted to 188 billion euros, i.e. around 15% of total compulsory levies. 97 and 7% of GDP. The main taxes are corporate income tax (IS), various property taxes and the corporate value-added tax (cotisation sur la valeur ajoutée des entreprises).

Details of direct taxes on companies and sole proprietorships in France from 2019 to 2022

Scope: these figures cover all companies (financial and non-financial) and sole proprietorships. They are therefore different from those used in 7.3 to analyze OP over the long term (which cover only non-financial companies). 98 ) and those used by INSEE in its structural business statistics (see Essentiel 1).

direct taxes on businesses

Source Les comptes de la Nation 2023 (tables covering the accounts of NFCs 7.101, EIs 7.102, SFs 7.201, GDP 1.106 and main taxes by category 3. 217) and Les entreprises en France en 2023 (for the income tax figure for sole proprietors_ we do not use the other data in this publication as they are less exhaustive than those presented in this module and some taxes, such as payroll tax, are presented as paid by businesses in full when this is not the case).

A few comments:

– Tax credits (16 billion in 2022) have not been deducted from corporate income tax, as they are considered as public expenditure (also known as tax expenditure) by national accounting and not as a lower tax levy.

-Many taxes (around 20 billion euros) are specific to certain sectors (and/or temporary) and therefore do not affect companies as a whole.

-In 2022, production taxes paid by businesses represented 71% of the total for this category of taxes, which also affect other economic players (households pay property tax; associations, hospitals, households, etc.). 99 pay payroll and labor taxes).

Production taxes

As we have seen, production taxes form part of a company’s operating costs. For this reason, they are the subject of regular demands by employers’ unions, and of controversial economic studies on their effects on competitiveness and employment. The argument often put forward is that they “increase companies’ production costs and prices, and reduce their competitiveness, to the detriment of employment and purchasing power”. 100 What’s more, they are higher in France than in the rest of Europe.

Production taxes in France and Europe

Taxes on production in France

Source Taxes on production, Fipeco

However, it is problematic to have a global reasoning on these production taxes. On the one hand, as noted above, there is no guarantee that lower taxes will translate into lower sales prices. It may also lead to an increase in the profits paid out to shareholders.

On the other hand, some of these taxes apply to most companies, but not all: others are specific to particular sectors and/or geographical areas. 101 Still others apply only to companies of a certain size. 102 Some taxes may be temporary. 103 Finally, beyond the budgetary aspect, certain taxes, such as eco-taxes, may have a business orientation objective (see 7.1): the primary aim of carbon quotas is to raise the price of CO2 emissions, while the tax on office space is intended to make this activity less profitable in an area with a high housing shortage.

Only a tax-by-tax analysis, in terms of the objectives pursued, any economic problems it poses, and what it brings in, therefore makes sense.

Corporate income tax (IS)

Since 2022, the statutory corporate income tax rate, as set out in the law 104 In France, the statutory rate of corporate income tax is 25% for profits over 38,200 euros (and 15% for profits below this figure).

Corporate income tax is calculated on “taxable profit”, which in simplified terms corresponds to pre-tax profit adjusted for the various possibilities provided by the Tax Code (various exemptions, deduction of certain income such as asset disposals taxed at different levels, etc.). 105

The relevant rate to look at is therefore the effective rate, calculated by dividing the amount of corporation tax actually paid by the amount of profit. This calculation is not easy, however, due to the lack of available data and numerous methodological issues. 106

In France, as elsewhere in the world, the statutory rate has been falling steadily since the 1980s. 107 This is one of the consequences of globalization and international competition, which is leading to a downward alignment of tax rates. Indeed, countries are engaged in tax competition in order to favor companies established on their territories, attract new ones and attract investors. The same type of mechanism leads to a race to the bottom in social and environmental terms.

This tax competition is active at the very heart of the European Union, as European treaties have always upheld the fiscal sovereignty of member states. In the 1990s, for example, Ireland adopted an ultra-competitive tax system, with a 12.5% tax rate on corporate profits, in order to attract investors. The Netherlands and Luxembourg can also be considered tax havens.

Average statutory corporate tax rate by region and decade

Worldwide corporate tax rates down since the 1980s

Source Corporate Tax Rates around the World, Tax Foundation, 2023

Lack of international tax harmonization and the existence of tax havens 108 also leads to tax avoidance practices. Multinationals pay their corporate tax on a country-by-country basis. They can therefore organize themselves to “shift” (legally, this is known as tax optimization, or by evading taxes) profits in such a way as to reduce the profits they make in countries where corporate tax rates are high.

These practices result in substantial tax losses for governments. Of course, it’s impossible to know exactly what these losses are. But it is possible to estimate their magnitude.

In their research Missing Profits, published in 2022, economists Thomas Tørsløv, Ludvig Wier and Gabriel Zucman estimate that, worldwide, almost 40% of multinationals’ profits (nearly $1,000 billion in 2019) are hidden in tax havens every year. For France, this would represent a loss of tax revenue of over $13 billion.

Taxes not paid by these companies are paid by other taxpayers, or lead to cuts in public services that are socially redistributive. This is an obvious source of injustice, and one that is perceived by citizens.

Furthermore, this leads to distortions of competition: not all companies can afford to pay the tax advisors required for tax optimization practices, nor can they afford to set up the complex legal arrangements needed to localize profits elsewhere than in their country of activity. As noted in a report by the Conseil d’analyse économique, this creates “a distortion of competition and the emergence of concentrated industries with a few companies having considerable market power.” 109 Tax law in fact favors multinationals to the detriment of other companies.

This deleterious situation eventually led to a reaction by States coordinated by the OECD with the Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) project. In October 2021, the G20 adopted the OECD’s proposal for a two-pillar reform concerning multinationals:

  • reallocate a minimum share of the company’s consolidated profits to the countries that generate them.
  • impose a minimum effective rate of 15% on consolidated profits.

To find out more, see Tax havens are an unacceptable source of tax losses for governments in our Finance module.

Companies communicate, advertise and report

Companies are subject to reporting obligations (on their activities, their financial situation and sometimes their extra-financial impacts) that depend on their size and sector of activity. These obligations are much more stringent and controlled for listed companies.

In addition to their legal obligations, companies are accountable to their stakeholders (bankers, shareholders, the State, customers or suppliers, employee representatives, etc.). Finally, they communicate with their customers and engage in advertising the products and services they sell.

All these opportunities to communicate allow us to highlight the company’s strengths and, as far as possible, avoid underlining its weaknesses.

Financial reporting

Historically, it was accounting and financial data that became the subject of reporting obligations, with two main types of recipient:

  • the State, since they are used to set tax levels for each company,
  • investors (creditors and shareholders), particularly for listed companies.

In the European Union, the Single Accounting Directive (2013) has standardized companies’ obligations in this area.

Financial statements must include at least the income statement, the balance sheet and its “notes”. “notes. 110

These documents are :

  • communicated to the tax authorities via the “liasse fiscale” in order to determine the tax payable, if any;
  • published in the relevant national company register (in France this is the Greffe du Tribunal de Commerce );
  • presented to the company’s Annual General Meeting, which approves the accounts and decides on the appropriation of profits if they are positive.

Above a certain size 111 and/or depending on the sector, companies have additional obligations.

They must publish a management report containing a “fair review of the company’s business, results and position, together with a description of the principal risks and uncertainties it faces”. 112 They are also required to have their financial statements audited by independent auditors.

Company groups are required to publish consolidated financial statements and management reports, which are drawn up by the “parent company” on the basis of the individual financial statements of the various subsidiaries it controls.

Measures taken to combat corruption and tax evasion

Large companies involved in the extraction of minerals, oil, natural gas or other materials or in the exploitation of primary forests must publish details of payments in excess of €100,000 they have made to governments during a financial year(Chapter 10 of Directive 2013/34/EU).

From 2024, the parent companies of multinational groups with consolidated annual sales in excess of €750 million must declare in a specific report made public the revenues, profits made, corporate income tax paid and number of employees country by country.(Chapter 10bis of Directive 2013/34/EU).

Listed companies have special obligations

Since 2005, they have been required to publish their financial statements in accordance with IFRS. 113 They are also required to disclose additional information for investors. 114 In France, they are required to produce a universal registration document that summarizes information about the company’s business and risk factors. 115 In addition, they are required to communicate information on a much more regular basis than unlisted companies (often on a quarterly basis), and to issue warnings in the event of a “landing” forecast (projected year-end earnings) below the budget indicated in the registration document.

All this information is centralized and published on the AMF website.

Non-financial reporting

Since the end of the 20th century, there has been a growing demand for companies to disclose information on the social and environmental dimensions of their activities, as well as on their governance practices. Initiated by “responsible” investors 116 and by major international institutions 117 this movement in favor of extra-financial reporting has gained in importance since 2015, the year of the COP21 climate conference. In a speech at Lloyds, Mark Carney, then Governor of the Bank of England, asserted that climate change was a factor in systemic financial risks. The issue of extra-financial reporting (climate in particular) then moved out of the departments dedicated to “responsible/sustainable/green/ethical” investment and gained strategic importance in the world of finance. Today, faced with the profusion of reference frameworks, standards and reporting norms, the time has come for standardization, with a confrontation between the Anglo-Saxon and European visions at the heart of the debate.

Emergence and development of an extra-financial reporting industry

The information needs of “responsible” investors have given rise to an ecosystem of players involved in reporting and making it possible. Associations and companies have been set up to propose reporting standards and/or to collect and analyze data. 118 The extra-financial rating business, evaluating companies on the basis of ESG (environmental, social and governance) criteria, on behalf of investors, has emerged within dedicated teams in asset management companies or banks, or via the creation of independent rating agencies.

New non-financial disclosure standards have also come from public initiatives such as the Task Force on Climate-related Financial Disclosures (TCFD). Launched by the Financial Stability Board in the wake of COP21, the TCFD proposed a corporate climate reporting framework in its 2017 report, which is now widely shared worldwide.

As the sector has developed, it has become highly concentrated. Today, the rating market is dominated by the world’s leading financial rating agencies (the “Big Three”: Moody’s, S&P and Fitch), who have positioned themselves by setting up their own rating systems and/or buying out the smaller historical agencies. 119

Europe pioneers ESG regulatory obligations

France is a forerunner in this field. In 2001, with the law on new economic regulations (art.116), it was the first country to include in its regulations the obligation for listed companies to report, in their management report, on how they take into account the social and environmental consequences of their activities. With each passing law (and in order to comply with European law), the reporting framework has been clarified, the number of companies concerned extended, and third-party control mechanisms introduced.

The European Union took up the subject in 2014 with the Non-Financial Reporting Directive (known as “NFRD”), which introduces the obligation for every company with more than 500 employees to produce a declaration of non-financial performance.

The initially very flexible framework was made more restrictive by the 2022 directive on the publication of sustainability information by companies (known as the “CSRD” for Corporate Sustainability Reporting Directive). Declarations must now be verified by an independent third-party organization. The scope of application has been extended to more companies, and an extraterritorial dimension has been introduced (non-European companies operating on EU territory may be concerned). Last but not least, the directive has improved the framework and harmonization of reporting with the definition of the “ESRS”(European Sustainability Reporting Standards), the first part of which (the “all-sector” standards) is to be implemented by the European Commission. 120 ) was adopted at the end of 2023.

Dual materiality at the heart of the standards battle

Today, there are two opposing visions of non-financial reporting on either side of the Atlantic, with a key sustainability issue at the heart of the debate: the materiality of reporting.

The European Union has introduced the principle of double materiality at the heart of the recently-issued ESRS standards. As Laurence Scialom notes, this is an important development because “it means recognizing that the responsibility of companies and financial institutions does not stop at their financial performance, and that they must also manage and take responsibility for the actual and potential negative impacts of their decisions on people, society and the environment”“”.

This is also the position adopted by China (for its listed companies from April 2026).

Definition – The principle of materiality

According to US GAAP, “materiality is an accounting principle that requires all items that are reasonably likely to influence investor decision-making to be recorded or disclosed in detail in a company’s financial statements”“”.

This principle has been extended to non-financial reporting, in particular to limit it to information that is relevant to the concrete challenges faced by the company.

  • Simple materiality” transposes the accounting principle and focuses on financial materiality. Reporting must focus on the risks of loss of value for the company, and therefore for its financiers, as a result of ESG (social, environmental and governance) risks.
  • Double materiality” is much broader: it includes not only ESG risks, but also the impacts the company has on the environment, society and its stakeholders (impact materiality).

On the other side of the Atlantic, theInternational Sustainability Standards Board (ISSB) 121 created at the end of 2021, is the EU’s main competitor in this field. Within the IFRS Foundation, the ISSB is the non-financial reporting equivalent of the IASB (International Accounting Standards Board), which created the IFRS international accounting standards.

In June 2023, the ISSB published IFRS S1 (on the information to be disclosed by companies about the risks and opportunities they face as a result of sustainability issues) and IFRS 2 (more specific to climate issues). A research agenda focusing on nature and human capital was also announced in 2024.

In each case, the logic is that of simple materiality, and is therefore in line with standard financial analysis: the important thing is to assess the risks for the company and its investors, not the impact of the company on its human and natural environment. This view of sustainability is deleterious: nature is seen as important (material) only in terms of its financial impact.

As Alexandre Rambaud rightly noted 122 the principle of simple materiality is in line with today’s dominant view that the main purpose of a company is to maximize profits in order to remunerate shareholders, who are only interested in financial gains. This is a very simplistic view of the company and of investors, who can consider dimensions other than profit. This is what the Asia Investing Group on Climate Change reminded the ISSB in 2022, in its response to the international consultation on the future IFRS S1 and S2 standards: “many investors have more holistic mandates [than those retained by the ISSB], which go beyond the sole creation of financial value.”

Beyond this battle of standards, we must not lose sight of the fact that transparency is only one of the tools of the ecological transition.

Reporting has positive aspects. Disclosure (and therefore research) of non-financial data enables companies to become aware of their impacts, a prerequisite for action. The information made public in this way also provides stakeholders (primarily investors, but also public bodies and NGOs) with the tools to challenge company practices.

However, transparency is far from sufficient to transform an organization’s business model, and at the macro-economic level to shift the economy towards a less carbon-intensive, extractive and predatory model. As noted in misconception 4, ESG ratings based on extra-financial reporting are no guarantee of responsible corporate practices, and even less of a massive redirection of financial flows. And for good reason, social and environmental indicators do not play on equal terms with financial data: companies’ strategic decisions are still largely dominated by financial performance objectives, whatever the human and ecological costs.

Consumer information

Companies communicate a great deal of information to their customers.

Historically, this first took the form of advertising: whether on the products themselves, displayed in our towns and cities, in the press, in dedicated brochures dropped in letterboxes, on television or on the Internet, advertising is omnipresent in modern life characterized by consumerism.

As we explain in a dedicated file, advertising today is problematic. It increases consumption and promotes unhealthy lifestyles, it can be dangerous in certain sectors such as health, it uses up considerable natural and financial resources, and it is not politically neutral (particularly in terms of the values it promotes).

Let’s emphasize here that advertising can be outrageous, misleading the consumer or even deceptive, boasting or suggesting qualities that the product does not have. In the ecological field, this type of practice is referred to as greenwashing. It was first used in 1986 in a short essay by Jay Westerfeld 123 an American activist who denounced the practice of hotels encouraging residents to reuse their towels on the grounds of saving the planet, when in fact the priority was to reduce cleaning costs. The first definition appeared in 1991 in a study on environmental advertising 124 and the word appeared in the Concise Oxford English Dictionary in 1999. Greenwashing can be used to make a product appear to have ecological qualities that it does not actually have, or more generally to make a company’s sustainable development strategy appear more ambitious than it is (while glossing over its negative impacts). These practices are all the more problematic in that it’s particularly difficult for consumers to decipher what’s real and what’s not when it comes to environmental issues.

Faced with this situation, legislators have (sooner or later and with varying degrees of force depending on the country) introduced provisions enabling companies to be prosecuted for misleading advertising. In particular, these take the form of legal action (led in France by consumer associations), which can lead to fines or compensation for damages. This type of provision has been extended – belatedly – to certain forms of greenwashing.

While advertising is one of the tools used by companies, regulations also require them to provide consumers with a wide range of other information. In France and Europe, legislators have extended the range of information to be included on products, whether in the wake of health scandals or in pursuit of sustainability objectives. There are also numerous public labels providing information on products.

Some examples of mandatory information and/or labels

  • Information on the composition of food products (and mention of potential allergens)
  • Places of origin (and traceability systems, particularly in the food sector)
  • Energy label to provide information on the consumption of household appliances, buildings or cars,
  • Nutri-score on the nutritional quality of processed food products
  • Repairability index to reduce electrical and electronic waste
  • European Ecolabel (and AB label in France) to guarantee a minimum of ecological product quality;
  • Textile Eco-score on the environmental quality of clothing

It’s not always easy for consumers to distinguish between official information and advertising. First of all, the companies concerned are actively involved in drawing up standards and the resulting “labels”. Thus, for example, the nutri-score has been the subject of intense lobbying by the agri-food industry to weaken its scope. 125 The HVE (high environmental value) label 126 label, which certifies farms, has come under intense criticism for the weak ecological guarantees it provides. A number of private labels and logos have also emerged, some of which go further than regulations (such as the Demeter label for agricultural products), but most of which are purely communication-driven. 127 This is very close to the greenwashing mentioned above.

Limiting our impact on nature is not enough: we need to reorient our business models.

For some, companies, being at the heart of employment and innovation, should be the focus of public policy attention, with priority given to ensuring their competitiveness and growth. Overall economic well-being would flow from such orientations 128 . For others, companies, subject to the “law of profit”, would be places of exploitation and predation, as well as the main cause of the destruction of nature and the enslavement of human by human. They should therefore be regulated to limit their weight in the economy and their impact, and even socialized. 129 or nationalize them 130 . Finally, others, in the wake of the sustainable development movement initiated by the 1987 Brundtland Report and accelerated by the 2002 Johannesburg Summit, believe that companies can contribute to the ecological transition provided they develop their social and environmental responsibility (a point we develop inMisconception 4 on CSR). In this section, we’ll be looking at the ecological impact of companies, and at the theories and practices that have emerged around less predatory or even contributory companies and business models.

Assessing the direct and indirect impacts of companies

Companies have a direct or indirect negative impact on nature

They consume ores and metals, energy and water; they kill living beings and destroy ecosystems, notably through extraction activities and the footprint of infrastructures and buildings; they emit greenhouse gases and chemical pollution, and produce waste, etc.

The impact on companies can be :

  • direct, when they relate to assets (machines, plants, vehicle fleets, etc.) controlled or operated by the company within its legal scope. 131 For example, the heating and floor space of a company-owned building, pollutants emitted by the production process, etc.
  • indirect when they are linked to activities located upstream (those of suppliers, for example the impact of a mine from which the minerals used by the company are extracted) or downstream (those of customers, for example the pollution linked to the use of cars by the customers of a car manufacturer) of the activity of the company itself.

The term footprint is used to refer to all these impacts: we speak of carbon footprint (see our Counting greenhouse gas emissions fact sheet), biodiversity footprint, water footprint, materials footprint, etc. 132 (which, for the moment, is essentially developed at the territorial level.

Clearly, companies have neither the same responsibilities nor the same room for manoeuvre when it comes to their direct or indirect impacts.

However, its capacity to act, and therefore its responsibility, is never zero. For upstream and downstream impacts, they are shared.

For example, a car manufacturer shares responsibility for greenhouse gas emissions and air pollutants with the car user. It has the opportunity to build and market cars that are less polluting to run. The user also has a responsibility linked to the car he or she has chosen to buy and the type of driving he or she does. Upstream in the value chain, automakers can force their suppliers to comply with demanding environmental and social specifications, while accepting to pay the price.

Food manufacturers and catering chains can use less-polluting or recyclable packaging; they can offer dishes that limit the use of meat products, etc. As with the automotive industry, they have room to maneuver when it comes to specifications. As with the automotive industry, they have room to maneuver when it comes to specifications. And here too, consumers have their share of responsibility.

It’s in the company’s interest to assess all its impacts

This enables the company to understand the extent to which its business model “depends” on the pollution it influences, both directly and indirectly. In this way, it can assess the risk of seeing its profitability undermined by regulations or tax measures aimed at limiting pollution, upstream or downstream of its legal perimeter. It also has a vested interest in knowing the strategic resources on which its production depends. The same applies, of course, to social issues.

The strategy of influencing public authorities to avoid regulatory or tax tightening may save time, but is clearly not ethically satisfactory (and sometimes makes recruiting young people more difficult) and not necessarily the best economically.

To assess its impacts, and then reduce them, the company can carry out or commission more or less detailed footprint calculations (see above) (by subsidiary, by site, by type of pollutant, etc.). It can also use life-cycle analysis methods to produce a multi-criteria environmental assessment of a product, service or process (or even the company itself) over its entire life-cycle, i.e. from extraction of the raw material to transformation into waste (or reuse).

Taking action: reducing impacts and transforming the company’s business model

Of course, evaluation is not a goal in itself. It is of interest only in a forward-looking perspective: the aim is to determine a roadmap, also known as a “transition plan”. 133 The aim is to determine a roadmap, also known as a “transition plan”, with a view to reducing the impacts considered, or even radically transforming the company’s business model.

With the orders of magnitude and the roadmap in hand, the company can quantify and then launch actions.

More often than not, when companies do take action, they are content to optimize what already exists to reduce their impact, without radically transforming their business.

These include :

  • optimize processes to save energy, water, raw materials and land, etc. ;
  • review the energy sources used (develop renewable energy supplies);
  • pay attention to the origin of raw materials (avoid metals from conflict zones, give preference to recycled materials, limit the use of chemicals or even replace them with green chemistry, etc.);
  • limit waste generation and chemical pollution (either treatment or redirection).
Genuine consideration of ecological issues means asking questions about a company’s purpose, its business model and its core activities.

To what extent does the company carry out an activity that contributes to the transition or, more generally, to the common good?

In certain sectors, such as education, healthcare or personal care, the contribution to the common good is obvious at first glance. In such cases, the aim is to focus on the implementation of the activity and its impact, both ecological and human (which is not insignificant, as a company can be predatory in its practices, whatever the field of activity). 134 ).

In others, answering this question requires major renunciations and reorientations. At macro-economic level, making a success of the transition means abandoning a number of activities, such as the exploitation of fossil fuels, the production and massive use of pesticides, single-use disposable products and so on. Within the company, this means giving up the most polluting and wasteful activities. This is what Sophie Robert-Velut, CEO of Laboratoires Expanscience, said in early 2023 when she announced that Mustela, one of the Group’s brands, would stop selling wipes in France in 2027 (representing 20% of the brand’s sales). This is also what some energy companies are doing, when they decide to sell their fossil fuel assets (or, better still, close them down) and redirect their activities towards renewable energies or energy efficiency.

Looking at the company’s business model means not just correcting economic activity to make it cleaner, but orienting or reorienting the core business to have a positive impact. Here are just a few examples:

  • replacing polluting products with less polluting ones: making bicycles (and building bicycle paths) instead of cars; producing or using recycled materials (e.g. aluminum, steel, textiles, paper, etc.) instead of virgin materials; producing renewable energy instead of fossil fuels;
  • business models based on extending product lifespans: repairing (if possible using recycled components) household appliances or electronic equipment, reuse, reconditioning (e.g. cell phones);
  • activities aimed at saving water or energy: production of insulating materials, energy-efficient home renovation, IT services aimed at reducing energy or water consumption (of buildings, equipment for businesses or households, etc.);
  • business models aimed at selling use (energy, mobility, laundry) rather than possession (the economy of functionality);
  • transforming activities directly linked to life so that they are regenerative rather than destructive: agroecology, agroforestry, bio-cosmetics, green chemistry etc. ;
  • Activities aimed at repairing the damage done: soil and ocean decontamination, soil renaturation, maintenance of natural areas, reforestation, etc.

In many cases, these products, infrastructures and processes can have both positive main effects and negative “collateral” effects.

That’s why :

  1. Having an ecological or “sustainable” corporate purpose doesn’t mean you don’t have to take care to minimize the impact of your activity (which inevitably exists);
  2. It is important to have an overall, rigorous and shared vision of all ecological impacts, as certain activities that are positive in one dimension can have negative impacts on another (e.g. the rail network is positive for the climate compared with the car, but destroys habitats and fragments territories, which has a negative impact on biodiversity).

This is why the European Commission has drawn up a taxonomy of economic activities based on their positive and negative impacts on 6 major environmental objectives (climate change mitigation and adaptation, biodiversity, water, pollution, circular economy).

European taxonomy: what’s it all about?

The European taxonomy is a classification designed to help companies and, above all, investors identify “environmentally sustainable” activities.

To qualify as such, an economic activity must meet four conditions:

1/ it contributes substantially to one or more of the 6 identified environmental objectives.135

There are three categories of economic activities that make a substantial contribution to one of the 6 environmental objectives: so-called “environmentally sustainable” activities have a positive impact on the objective in question; so-called “enabling” activities enable other activities to contribute to achieving one of the six objectives; finally, so-called “transitional” activities (which only concern the global warming mitigation objective) are those that perform best in a sector when there is no economically or technologically viable low-carbon alternative.

2/ it does not cause significant harm to any of the other five objectives (the “do not harm” principle).

3/ it must respect minimum social and human rights guarantees (as defined in several international texts).136

4/ To assess the extent to which conditions 1 and 2 have been met, a list of technical criteria has been drawn up. For the time being, it concerns 90 economic activities and only the first two environmental objectives (mitigation and adaptation to global warming). The list of criteria can be consulted on the Taxonomy Compass .

To find out more: The EU taxonomy navigator brings together a number of well-designed tools to help you find your way around. Reading the Taxonomy Regulation (2020) will also help you understand the main principles. See also a clear explanation on the AMF website.

Conceptualizing new business models: circular economy, contributive enterprise, regenerative enterprise

Basing a company’s economic value on its contribution to the common good

As we saw in the previous section, the recognition of ecological issues has led to the emergence (or highlighting) of new fields of activity and business practices. This movement has been accompanied by attempts to conceptualize what could be new business models for companies.

In 2010, for example, the Ellen MacArthur Foundation was launched to popularize the notion of the circular economy (first mentioned in the 1970s). Although the concept has not yet been defined in a standardized way, it broadly contrasts the current linear economic model (extracting materials, transforming them, consuming them, then throwing them away) with a model in which the flow of living and non-renewable materials (minerals in particular) is “circularized”, i.e., one person’s waste becomes the new raw material for production.

This all-encompassing concept has enabled many of the economic models and practices that have emerged at the turn of the 21st century to be placed under the same banner: eco-design, the economy of functionality, recycling, repair, reuse, industrial ecology and so on.

The 7 pillars of the circular economy

the-7-pillars-circular-economy

Source : Métamorphoses

Other concepts have also been proposed.

In a book published in 2021, Fabrice Bonnifet, Director of Sustainable Development for the Bouygues Group and Chairman of C3D, developed the notion of a contributive company, defined as a company “that contributes materially to common goods (in the sense of the Sustainable Development Goals – SDGs) and to the well-being of the individual”.

The concept of regenerative enterprise, which emerged in the 2010s 137 refers to organizations that have embarked on two parallel movements: “the first is to reduce its negative impacts to incompressible thresholds; the second is to generate net positive impacts on ecosystems and human communities through a reconnection with the living”“.

Not all companies can be regenerative on their own perimeter, as this requires a direct link with the living world. Others can contribute to “socio-ecological regeneration” by forming (or becoming part of) “cooperative ecosystems of players, some of whom have a direct link with non-human living things, so that the regenerative ambition relates to this collective of players, much more than to each individual company.”

The importance of scaling up

Whatever the concept used, it is important not to limit the analysis to the microeconomic dimension (one company, one sector), but to consider the impact at the macro level. As long as these new models only concern a few pioneering companies, often cited as examples, the overall impact will remain limited, if not non-existent.

There are many well-documented reasons for this:

  • The risk of rebound effects: when a company’s activity enables it to reduce consumption of energy, water or other raw materials, the financial savings made (whether by the company or the consumer) can be transferred to additional purchases or production, thereby canceling out the positive impact at global level.
  • The risk of new products adding to rather than replacing “traditional” production is well illustrated in the energy sector, where renewable energies have not replaced fossil fuels. This is also the case in the textile sector, where the development of second-hand products has not prevented the growth of fast fashion.
  • The circularity of materials is not infinite: after repeated recycling, the quality of most materials deteriorates, and after repeated reuse/reconditioning, product performance declines: end-of-life is inevitable, even if it can be postponed.
  • The savings in natural resources made possible by models based on circularity (recycling, reuse, reconditioning, functionality) are rendered obsolete as long as the consumption of these same resources continues to grow on a global scale. François Grosse’s work clearly illustrates this point: “if material consumption grows by more than 3% a year – as has been the case for iron and copper over the past century – recycling even 90% of our waste has a derisory effect on resource conservation.” 138

Scaling up requires public intervention

To promote new business models, the role of public authorities is essential. This means using all the tools of economic policy (taxation, regulation, public procurement and investment, subsidies, monetary policy) to improve or even build the profitability of transition projects and sectors. Indeed, whether we’re talking about launching a business based on one of the new economic models, or transforming a company to reduce its impact and reposition it in sectors and practices that contribute to the transition, profitability is by no means self-evident.

The competitive environment is unfavorable to transition projects

Competition with existing modes of production and consumption, whether within the same company or in the global economic environment, puts the players behind the new models at a disadvantage. On the one hand, the promoters of “business as usual” are powerful, structured and well-established, as demonstrated, for example, by the difficulty many countries have in putting an end to coal mining, even though this is one of the priorities in the fight against global warming. On the other hand, sustainable activities have to compete with activities that have mature technologies, widespread skills, amortized investments and infrastructures in place. The existing system sets the “selling price” against which the profitability of ecological solutions is confronted. Public investment, coupled with regulations favoring new products or markets, is therefore essential to help innovation, investment and the structuring of sectors. In many cases, public impetus or even supervision is necessary to ensure the existence of certain sectors. This is the case, for example, with recycling or product lifespan extension (reuse, repair, reconditioning). The manufacturers of the initial products must design them in such a way as to enable repair, reconditioning and, ultimately, the recovery of materials – activities which they will not necessarily carry out themselves.

Demand for sustainable products and investments is not self-evident

As far as households are concerned, individual gains in well-being are often not perceptible, since the aim is not to provide access to new goods and services, but to change the way they are produced and consumed. Sometimes, these gains are distant in time (limiting global warming by reducing GHG emissions) or in space (reducing the destruction of mines by using recycled materials or reconditioned products). More often than not, these are gains in collective well-being. Switching from coal-fired electricity to renewable production brings more benefits to the community (reduced risks, waste,CO2 emissions, air pollution) than to the individual. Finally, in many cases, the improvement in quality of life will only be felt if the majority of the population makes the switch. If an individual decides to take public transport instead of his car, he will only see an impact on the polluted air of his city if the majority of city-dwellers do as he does.

On the business side, the question of demand also arises. This is particularly obvious in the case of recycled materials: without a regulatory framework (such as a mandatory percentage of recycled materials in new products), price would be the only factor driving demand. Yet raw material prices are subject to fluctuations that are hardly conducive to the structuring of supply chains.

Lack of incentive for business leaders to act in the current economic environment

Without even mentioning the scale of the changes required to transform a company’s business model, there are many obstacles at work right from the first levels of action to take ecological impacts into account.

  • Lack of information and/or conviction about the scale of the ecological crisis can lead to a failure to prioritize actions in this area in relation to day-to-day business; a manager may order impact calculations (out of legal obligation or for image reasons) without taking action for lack of conviction (which can result from a lack of information).
  • The contradiction between financial profitability requirements and climate, environmental and social commitments.
  • Additional costs incurred by actions (even measurement and diagnostic actions cost money, if only in terms of staff time).

These additional costs are generally considered to be detrimental to the company’s margins or even competitiveness, without necessarily providing any tangible compensation. If managers are convinced that the price of energy and raw materials will rise in the future, they may be able to justify winning actions on two fronts: lower future costs and reduced ecological impact. But this is not always the case, given the uncertainty that weighs on any cost projection.

Even if they are aware of the issue or have received training, managers can’t see why they should degrade their company’s performance for the common good, and with the added risk of marginal action if other players do nothing. It’s always the same paradox at work: the immediate interest of an economic agent can be in contradiction with the general interest, even if in the long term the degradations involved turn out to be dramatic for everyone.

Transition projects bring social and environmental benefits that are not taken into account in pricing.

This is particularly true of projects aimed at restoring ecosystems in order to preserve biodiversity and regain the benefits of the ecological services we derive from them. It’s hard to find the intrinsic profitability of a project to clean up soil, create or restore wetlands (which can generate a local economy: fishing, ecotourism, etc.) or artificial reefs (which can be used for fishing or underwater ecotourism).

Models that require long-term investment

In a book on the circular economy, published in 2023, Franck Aggeri Rémi Beulque and Helen Micheaux highlight seven key points for managing projects of this type (p49). In particular, the authors emphasize the need for collective exploration and experimentation in these projects, for which there is no market, and for which all existing tools and routines (calls for tender, ex ante cost evaluation) are ill-suited because they are part of the linear economy. They also underline the need to be part of a local dynamic, an ecosystem of diverse players, both for the implementation of projects throughout the supply chain, and for the design of new standards, tools and methods. All this requires time and consequent investment, with no guarantee of profitability.

Even when investments are intrinsically profitable, there are problems if they are made over too long a timescale. This is the case, for example, with energy-efficient building renovation, which is essential if we are to achieve our climate objectives. The initial investment is repaid through energy savings over 10-20 years. Households therefore have to choose between this renovation, another investment or immediate consumption. What’s more, many households simply don’t have the means to invest. It’s hardly surprising, then, that the renovation market is struggling to take off.

The size of the initial investment has an impact on the economics of projects over their lifetime: the cost of financing is a determining factor in project profitability. For example, the costs of a coal-fired power plant are divided between initial investment and operation; whereas for a photovoltaic plant, costs are highly concentrated on the initial investment. The cost of financing will therefore be much more decisive for a photovoltaic plant, since it depends on the monetary (interest rates) and regulatory (favorable or unfavorable to the sector) environment, and its predictability over time.

All of which goes to show that it’s pointless to expect all entrepreneurs to go “green” at the same time, especially as in many sectors, it’s not a question of creating new activities, but rather of getting existing companies to do business differently. This is why the role of the public authorities remains essential: they must try to align the interests of private players with the general interest. This is what is done, for example, when pollutants are banned, when environmental taxation is introduced or ecological regulations are put in place, and so on. However, given the scale of current local and global ecological degradation, this is clearly not enough.

Multinational companies have excessive powers

In this issue of Essentiel, we’ll take a look at very large multinational companies. Multinationals 139 are groups of companies with subsidiaries in countries other than that of the parent company. There are some 80,000 of them worldwide 140 .

With regard to size, what criteria are used to define a company as “very large”? Insee considers that a large company meets at least one of the following two conditions: it must have at least 5,000 employees; and it must have sales of over 1.5 billion euros and total assets of over 2 billion euros. Forbes ranking of the world’s largest companies 141 is based on sales, market capitalization, profits and assets. In the 2023 ranking 142 the largest company is an American bank, JP Morgan, followed by the oil company Saudi Aramco, and three Chinese banks. The leading French company is TotalEnergies, ranked 21st with sales of over $250 billion. Forbes doesn’t provide information on the number of employees, but it’s possible to situate the orders of magnitude. Ten companies employ more than 500,000 people, the top three being Walmart, Amazon (each in excess of one million), and Foxconn (Apple’s subcontractor in China). In France, in the private sector, Téléperformance, the world leader in call centers, will have the highest number of employees in 2023 (over 400,000).

This gigantism is due to the concentration of companies, which can be seen in many sectors (digital, energy, agri-food, finance, pharmaceuticals, mining, commodities trading, etc.), as will be seen in a few examples below. In other words, the race for size is not a law of history. In fact, in the USA, for example, the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 provided a serious framework for it.

Economic concentration: the paradox of free competition

According to the most widespread teaching in economics, free and perfect competition is the source of economic efficiency and optimum performance. On the other hand, dominant positions and market concentration are reprehensible, notably because they lead to less favorable prices for consumers. And yet, they occur almost everywhere in the world, and in all sectors. The paradox is clear: the economic theory that justifies the free market is based on an assumption that is empirically contradicted by the way the free market itself operates. Regulations are obviously needed to prevent companies from growing – which means opposing free competition…

We’ll now return to the source of this paradox.

The economic argument that free and perfect competition leads to an optimum is based on a representation of the economy in which each company has only a small market share and no influence on prices. They are said to be “price takers”: having no significant influence on market prices, which are set by the confrontation of diffuse players, they are obliged to “take” them as they are.

On the contrary, large companies can be “price makers” when they have a sufficiently dominant position to influence the price.143

The aim of competition law is to prevent dominant positions on a market, which would prevent the entry of new players. In this line of reasoning, the main problem with a monopoly or oligopoly is the formation of rents to the benefit of producers and to the detriment of consumers.

The central hypothesis that demonstrates that a competitive situation with a multiplicity of agents leads to an optimum is the “law” of diminishing returns.

In this case, the cost of the last unit sold is higher than that of the previous one (or conversely, with the same quantity of a factor of production used, production increases less and less). Historically, this law (formulated by Turgot, then taken up and improved by David Ricardo) was demonstrated in the agricultural sector, where land was supposed to be farmed in decreasing order of fertility. In an economic sector where yields are indeed decreasing, it’s easy to understand that size – and therefore concentration – is not an asset.

In many economic sectors, however, returns are increasing 144 . The best-known example is the digital sector, where the software industry is a zero-marginal-cost industry: the last copy of a software product costs nothing to produce, and is as profitable as possible. Increasing returns drive size and concentration: the bigger a player is, the more it can lower its prices and drive out the competition. In fact, the vast majority of mergers are justified by the economies of scale they bring.

In practice, the decision to sanction a dominant position or to refuse a merger is a difficult one. It obviously depends on the details of the applicable law, and rests on a delicate analysis: which market is being considered, on which criteria should the decision be based, and so on. Such a decision is also politically delicate, in a context of globalization, where the race for size may on the contrary be encouraged (to have “world leaders”) in other countries.

On a more severe level, competition law prohibits and penalizes cartels. 145 . Here, the idea is less debatable: agreeing on prices is clearly an obstacle to competitors who do not belong to the oligopoly.

Price control and the formation of rents are obviously not just anecdotal social issues. In the food sector, for example, the presence of powerful oligopolies in production, trading and distribution (see box) can lead, via price rises – which may be exacerbated by the financialization of these markets and the resulting speculative movements – to severe food tensions and even famines. 146 . Such situations can arise without any improvement in the situation of farmers, who do not benefit from the price rises suffered by consumers.

Concentration in the agri-food sector

The agri-food world is at the heart of the destruction of biodiversity, and is a major emitter of greenhouse gases (via fertilizers, and methane from ruminants and rice paddies). In the face of the multiplicity of peasants and farmers, we can observe a considerable concentration of players in this sector, as shown by the report Trade and development 2023 report, which identified fourteen major groups dominating the sector. The top four alone – Cargill, Archer Daniels Midland, Bunge and Louis Dreyfus – control some 70% of the world cereals market. In 2022, they achieved a cumulative profit of over $17 billion, almost triple their 2020 results. In the beer sector 147 three industrial groups bring together more than 1,400 brands.

We should also mention the upstream concentration of agricultural machinery: John Deere, CNH industrial, Kubota (Japan) and AGCO account for 53% of the market. In crop protection: Bayer-Monsanto (Germany), Syngenta-ChemChina (China), Dupont-Dow (USA), BASF (Germany) account for 84% of the market.

What’s more, these companies are at the heart of the massive financialization of agricultural commodity markets, and are therefore linked to powerful financial players, generating high volatility in agricultural commodity prices. Recent years of tension and risk of shortages on agricultural markets have increased appetites tenfold, driven by the lure of profit.

Questionable or even reprehensible practices by very large companies

Without going any further into the economic analysis, we will review some of the social and environmental damage caused by our activities. 148 that these very large companies can generate as a result of their power and financial resources (either individually, or acting in concert via visible professional organizations or lobbying structures).

Shaping not only our physical world but also our lifestyles and desires

Before even mentioning specific, visible damage, let’s note that multinational corporations profoundly shape not only our physical world, but also our lifestyles, our desires, our entertainment… It’s multinationals that design and build infrastructures (ports, airports, roads, factories, etc.) and large buildings (hospitals, hotels, etc.), homogenizing the whole world: what’s the difference between a luxury hotel in Kuala Lumpur, New York, Paris or Bangalore? Multinationals set fashion and taste. Consider the fact that L’Oréal spends a third of its sales on luxury products. 149 on marketing and advertising to impose its products and its vision of the ideal woman or man. Multinationals created the disposable world. Who remembers the arrival of the first disposable lighters, in the era when Shein encourages us to change clothes every day and throw away the ones we wore yesterday? Multinationals impact our entertainment, imposing their heroes (Mickey Mouse and Spiderman are known the world over). All in all, they reduce cultural diversity and, in the agricultural sector, biological diversity and the diversity of our landscapes. Finally, they influence our social behavior and opinions. 150

Grabbing natural resources in underdeveloped countries, devastating the environment

Extractive industries (fossil fuels, ores and metals) are predators of nature. This reality was well documented in the study Controverses minières – Volet 1 – Caractère prédateur et dangereux (June 2021), produced by the SystExt association, which specializes in mining. In poor countries, this predation is also at the expense of the local population. Directly, by devastating the environment in which they live, or even by resorting to armed violence. 151

Indirectly, by not sufficiently rewarding the proceeds of these extractions. Production-Sharing Agreements (PSAs), which are gradually replacing concessions, are not always equitable, on two levels: the state owning the resource may recover only a small share of the rent, and the part of the rent recovered may not benefit the populations of the country concerned.

These questions are permanent for the entire global extractive industry, which, as we shall see in the box, is highly concentrated, giving the world leaders considerable power and greatly unbalancing the balance of power in their favor.

Concentration in the mining and mineral commodities trading sectors

The world of mining and trading in mineral raw materials is experiencing the same concentration and financialization as the world of agriculture. A small dozen multinationals control the vast majority of mining activity (Rio Tinto, BHP Billiton, Vale SA, Tata Steel, Anglo American, Jiangxi Copper Corporation, Dundee Precious, Freeport-McMoRan).

And, as with agricultural commodities and fossil fuels, the trading of these raw materials is highly financialized (just to mention a few specialized traders: Vitol, Trafigura, Gunvor, Mercuria). Some of these players (such as Glencore, with GlencoreXstrata ) have specialized trading subsidiaries.

Influence or even put pressure on political decision-makers to weaken regulations that would be unfavorable to them

Lobbying has become a commonplace practice. However, for a company or group of companies, lobbying means influencing political decision-makers in their own interests. 152 responsible for the general interest. At the European Parliament, for example, a study by the NGO Agir pour l’environnement, published in 2024, highlighted the budgets charged by lobbying teams 153 . As Novethic reports 154 reports, “the 5,800 lobbies registered under the banners ‘Trade and Professional Associations’ and ‘Companies & Groups’ spent between 965 million and 1.3 billion euros on their lobbying activities over the last eleven months surveyed”.

This pressure can lead to “regulator capture” or regulatory capture, a term suggested by the “Nobel Prize in Economics” 155 George Stigler in 1982, to refer to the fact that regulatory authorities are controlled by private interests. 156

In the case of climate change, the lobbying practices of oil companies and the financial resources deployed are now well documented. 157 . Another example is the Energy Charter Treaty, which enables companies to attack states that adopt regulatory measures (possibly to preserve the climate) contrary to their interests.

This pressure on countries can go as far as making them compete on social and environmental tax grounds. The media regularly report on projects to locate factories or head offices, where competition between countries enables companies to obtain subsidies or reductions in social charges and taxes. On this vast issue, the main concern is the global race to the bottom in terms of corporate taxes. A case in point is Stellantis, the company created by the merger of PSA, Fiat and Chrysler, which is headquartered in the Netherlands for obvious tax reasons. 158 . It could be said that the Netherlands submits to pressure from multinationals to attract them and their jobs. This is even clearer for Ireland.

Develop tax avoidance strategies that reduce state resources

Multinationals have the means to hire top-level tax specialists, sometimes from tax administrations, to adapt their organizations and financial flows between companies to suit national tax systems, in order to minimize tax liabilities. These practices have long been known, and considerable work has been done under the aegis of the OECD to limit their scope. One of its key players, Pascal Saint-Amans, describes this work in his book Paradis fiscaux Comment on a changé le cours de l’histoire (Seuil, 2023). This work has made it possible to considerably reduce banking secrecy in OECD countries (with the introduction of reporting obligations), and also to tackle corporate tax avoidance, with the introduction of a worldwide minimum tax of 15%. But the book gives numerous examples of how multinationals are working to counter any progress in this area. And for these reasons, we still have a long way to go before our tax systems become more socially just.

To find out more about the mechanisms and amounts “lost” through corporate tax evasion, see our Tax evasion and tax havens factsheet.

Control the media, possibly by buying them

In France, most of the major media are owned or controlled by powerful groups controlled by billionaires and/or their families: Vincent Bolloré and Bernard Arnaud and their families, Xavier Néel, Rodolphe Saadé, the Dassault family, the Bouygues family…

Rupert Murdoch, the billionaire owner of Fox News and the Times, is a case in point.

French media: who owns what?

carte-medias-france

Source Le Monde Diplomatique

Map updated in December 2023.

Influencing election results

This is evident in the United States, where there are no limits on campaign financing. 159 The emblematic case of the Koch family, whose fortune comes from oil, has a proven influence on the climatoskepticism of the Republican camp.

Total spending by candidates in the second round of the U.S. presidential election (in millions of dollars)

expenses-candidates-presidents-USA-elections

Source American presidential election: when billions rain down on candidates, Les Echos (05/03/2024)

More recently 160 Elon Musk and other billionaires pledged tens of millions of dollars to support Donald Trump’s campaign 161 . In other countries, multinationals can play a direct role in elections. Let’s recall ITT’s involvement 162 in the destabilization of Chilean President Allende. In Africa, the Bolloré group’s role in elections (in Togo and Guinea) has been established in court. 163

We’re only giving a few examples here, but to find out more, we recommend Julia Cagé’s book, Le prix de la démocratie (Fayard, 2018).

Bribing civil servants or political staff in countries where this is possible or even systematically practiced

The Observatoire des multinationales website gives several examples of these practices.

The Elf affair in 1994 revealed just such French practices in Africa. In autocratic countries, or in countries where the administration is weak and poorly paid, it is difficult to do business without resorting to bribes and other occult practices.

It’s obviously easier for large multinationals with the financial and human resources to do so. According to World Bank estimates, quoted by Martin Sajdik 164 every year, “between $1,000 and $2,000 billion is lost to corruption, or 10 times the annual budget of the 34 member countries of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development combined. […]”. The costs of corruption are not just financial. Corruption erodes confidence in public institutions, compromises environmental protection and exacerbates poverty and inequality. 165

Spreading toxic products

Multinationals may be viewed positively in some countries, where they create jobs, invest and, more generally, contribute to economic development. But if they are in a dominant position, they can abuse this position to sell products that may prove harmful. These products may be distributed with the “consent” of the populations affected by a project (or by the dissemination of a product or process) or “used” to test a drug. 166 . They are not obliged to bribe politicians or buy the consent of populations to obtain it. We remember the milk powder scandal 167 in the 1970s; more recently, Nestlé has been accused of adding sugar to its baby products, thereby encouraging obesity 168 . Let’s take examples from developed countries: American opioid addiction is an unprecedented scandal and tragedy 169 pollution by PFAS, “eternal pollutants”. 170 in the United States, Europe and the rest of the world. Finally, let’s mention, among many other projects of this type, the EACOP project developed by TotalEnergies, which boasts of its benefits for local populations, even though it is climatically destructive and has considerable environmental and social impacts. 171

Exercise domination over their subcontractors in order to impose degraded working conditions or excessive environmental pressures on them

In 2013, the collapse of Rana Plaza 172 in Bangladesh, which caused the deaths of over 1,000 people, prompted reflection on the duties and responsibilities of parent companies towards their subsidiaries, suppliers and subcontractors 173 . In 2024, a U.S. jury found that Chiquita (formerly United Fruit Company 174 which gave rise to the expression “banana republic”) responsible for the deaths of eight people 175 at the hands of the paramilitary AUC militia, paid by the multinational to “protect its interests” and “resolve” conflicts with workers and unions.

France was a pioneer, passing a duty of care law in 2017. At the end of April 2024, the European Parliament passed a European directive, the CS3D, on this duty of vigilance. 176 which aims to oblige companies of a certain size to monitor the risks of non-compliance with labor and environmental law throughout their value chain. More specifically, the directive requires these companies (and their upstream and downstream partners) to prevent, stop or mitigate their negative impact on human rights and the environment, including at the sourcing, production and distribution levels. This includes slavery, child labor, labor exploitation, erosion of biodiversity, pollution or destruction of natural heritage.

Corrupting or instrumentalizing scientists to produce studies that instill doubts in the minds of citizens

Two American academics, Naomi Oreskes and Erik M. Conway, are responsible for 177 to have identified and documented a method deliberately used by major corporations to create doubt and confusion in the minds of citizens and political decision-makers, when scientific evidence of the negative effects of some of their products becomes convincing and well known. The strategy is not to deny this evidence, but to create doubts in consumers’ minds by putting forward other data or scientific findings: the tobacco industry 178 Faced with the risks of smoking-related cancer, the tobacco industry has financed research to cast doubt on these links, by highlighting, for example, other causes of lung cancer; the industry has then financed pharmacies to disseminate the information generating doubt. This strategy has been used in a number of fields, including climate change. It is within the reach of only the largest corporations, which are the only ones capable of mobilizing top-flight scientists and financing research and communication or lobbying firms. The energy sector, which is highly concentrated, has participated in these manipulation campaigns.

Concentration in the energy sector

Less than 60 producers (multinationals or state-owned companies) of oil, gas, coal and cement are directly linked to 80% of global fossilCO2 emissions since the Paris Agreement (see the Carbon Majors database). This database also shows that 122 entities are linked to 72% of allCO2 emissions from fossil fuels and cement since the start of the industrial revolution. Chinese state coal production tops the list, accounting for 14% of historical globalCO2 emissions. This is more than double the proportion of the former Soviet Union, in second place, and more than three times that of Saudi Aramco, in third. As for the French major TotalEnergies, it develops hydrocarbons in the most countries in the world -53 countries-, taking the risk of locking entire economies into new dependencies on fossil fuels.

Preconceived notions

Only businesses create wealth and jobs

Companies (by which I mean private and commercial) are seen by some as the essential source of wealth and employment, while other players (public or voluntary) are seen as being of little use or even harmful to economic activity, as they live off the backs of these companies.

This misconception is based on Say’s Law. Developed over 200 years ago, this “law” postulates that any new supply of goods or services automatically creates its own demand. Businesses would thus be at the origin of all economic activity, and therefore of jobs. The public policies that stem from such beliefs are well identified. These are the so-called supply-side policies, which aim to make life easier for private companies by limiting regulations and “rigidities” in the labor market (i.e., by simplifying the labor code), reducing the burden of taxation and social charges, and deregulating regulated sectors (cabs, notaries, etc.). On this last point, it may indeed be true that excessive barriers to entry create rents, and prevent other private players from entering a market where they could innovate, create wealth and employment. However, lifting regulations doesn’t magically create jobs; in fact, the opposite may be true.

More generally, the idea that only private-sector companies create wealth and jobs does not stand up to analysis. We have already seen in Essentiel 2 that Insee’s analysis of the productive system concerns less than 60% of the value added generated by the French economy in 2021. Below, we focus on the question of employment.

Based on available data 1 in France, more than three out of every ten salaried jobs are outside the private and commercial sector.

Breakdown of salaried employment in France by type of employer

repartition-emploi-salarie-france

Source For the voluntary sector: Les chiffres clefs de la vie associative 2023 (p14). For other employers: Estimations d’emploi – Insee Résultats – L’emploi en France en 2021 (table t103).

Non-market jobs, sometimes considered “unproductive”, are not only necessary to economic life but often vital to it.

The non-profit sector is vast: it covers public services and services provided by associations (part of thesocial economy).

We won’t get into the debate about the size of the public sector here. Let’s simply note that companies and citizens benefit – without always realizing it (precisely because they don’t pay for them directly) – from public services such as security, justice, infrastructure quality, administrative services in the broadest sense of the term, and so on.

As far as the voluntary sector is concerned, let’s mention just a few examples: charities that deliver food to the poorest of the poor prevent millions of people in France from becoming undernourished. Parents are happy to see the vast majority of volunteers in sports clubs and children’s cultural services.

In addition, “non-market services” (personal care, culture, etc.) provide essential work for those who are employed, and essential “benefits” for those who benefit from them. These services are often not as profitable as private capital would like them to be, and it would be absurd to privatize them for ideological reasons.

There’s no proof that the private sector is more efficient

Water and waste management, for example, is sometimes carried out by private companies and sometimes by the public sector. The question of good management depends on the specific situation and context. There are at least as many examples going one way as the other.

In the medical field, international comparisons cast doubt on the idea that the private sector is “cheaper”. When it comes to dependency and retirement, do private Ehpads do better than public structures? In light of the ORPEA scandal 2 scandal, we have every right to doubt it. Private operators launching or developing the retirement home business are primarily interested in real estate and its financial value. They see the care and attention required by the elderly as costs to be optimized, which could undermine the profitability of the business.

However, it’s important to avoid Manichaeism: private Ehpads can be well managed (if the financial package leaves enough room for salaries and purchases essential to the comfort of residents, and if investors’ return requirements are reasonable). Public Ehpads can also be badly managed. The ORPEA affair, however, served as an eye-opener for a sector that was largely in financial difficulties as a result of the COVID, the staffing problems that ensued and the increased costs associated with the energy consequences of the war in Ukraine.

We need to define what we consider to be “wealth creation”.

To equate wealth creation with the value added generated by companies – and, by extension, at national level, with GDP and growth – is extremely simplistic.

A country is first and foremost rich in its wealth in the broadest sense, as we explain in the module on GDP. More generally, a state is rich in everything that makes it a good place to live. It would be preferable to speak of prosperity or social well-being. Services aimed at preserving ecosystems, which are often unprofitable and provided by the public sector, contribute to a country’s wealth. Social and medical services contribute to quality of life and health, a major indicator of a country’s prosperity. 3

Increasing labor productivity is not all good news

Labour productivity is the ratio of output produced to the labour required to produce it. 4 . As we show in the module on Work and Unemployment, spectacular productivity gains over the past two centurieshave “freed” some human beings from back-breaking manual labor. It cannot be denied that this increased productivity is largely the result of companies raising capital, investing in machinery and improving processes.

It would be absurd not to recognize the value of this liberation. But not to the point of making it a mantra, and directing all economic activity towards this progress alone, to the detriment of all others. The pursuit of productivity at all costs can, in fact, prove harmful. For example, in the personal care or education sectors, time spent is often a source of quality (and therefore value) in the service rendered. To describe these sectors as unproductive (because their productivity is not increasing) is simply ridiculous!

Hiring does not necessarily mean creating new jobs

It all depends on the context. For example, Amazon, which has declared that it will create 4,000 jobs in France by 2021, has also destroyed jobs, but with its competitors or similar companies. The balance sheet is not easy to establish without a specific study.

We can also assume that a company that is “doing well” is more productive than its competitors, and therefore “destroys” jobs, all other things being equal. Indeed, if it is economically more efficient, it employs fewer people than its competitors.

Managers should only be concerned with creating value for their shareholders

Most people today would say that companies have only one goal: to maximize shareholder wealth, as measured by share price. Other goals – serving customers, making good products, providing good jobs – are considered legitimate objectives only insofar as they increase “shareholder value”.

Lynn A. Stout, 2012

Lynn A. Stout is Professor of Business Law at Cornell School of Law. Lynn A. Stout, Professor of Business Law at Cornell School of Law, transcribes a widely held view that has shaped the governance and practices of most major corporations over the past few decades. It leads to a focus on short-term profit, which is damaging in ecological and social terms, and even to the long-term viability of the company itself. 5 (seeEssentiel 5 and our module on finance). However, as we shall see, this opinion has no legal or economic basis.

When did the ideological domination of shareholder value as the company’s primary objective begin?

The questioning of corporate purpose is relatively recent

This question arose at the beginning of the 20th century, with the emergence of large companies listed on the stock exchange and owned by a multitude of small shareholders. Prior to this, the question had not really arisen: as most companies were controlled and managed by one or more highly-involved shareholders (the founder, his family or close associates), their purpose depended on their will, and could be varied (profit, entrepreneurial adventure, the long-term health and growth of the company itself, etc.).

In large listed companies, a different form of management is emerging. They are no longer run by the founders or their descendants, but by executives/managers hired for this purpose by boards of directors (elected by the General Meeting of Shareholders, seeEssentiel 4 on governance).

Hence the emergence of questions about the role of these managers. Should they manage the company solely with a view to serving shareholders, or with more varied objectives in mind? For most of the 20th century, the second, so-called “managerial” philosophy prevailed, but things changed from the 1970s onwards.

Milton Friedman: the company at the service of shareholder value

In the 19070s, the economists of the Chicago School 6 developed a rhetoric according to which economic analysis would “prove” that the purpose of a company was to make money for its “owners”, i.e. the shareholders (which was false, as we shall see later). The best way to assess a company’s performance would be to look at the evolution of its share price on the market.

This thinking is epitomized by Milton Friedman, leader of the Chicago School. In 1970, he wrote an article for the New York Times with the explicit title “The Social Responsibility of Business is to Increase its Profits”.

In it, he takes up a thesis already developed in his book Capitalism and Freedom (1962): the idea that a company could have a social responsibility other than making profits for its shareholders is subversive, even dangerous, because it amounts to entrusting private individuals (the company’s managers) with the power to decide what the overall interests of society are.

Agency theory: aligning the interests of managers with those of shareholders

Agency theory explores how to ensure that the company effectively serves the shareholder’s objectives.

According to this theory, “most organizations are no more than legal fictions that serve to link a set of contractual relationships between individuals.” 7 The company is not an entity as such, but “a knot of contracts between individuals”. Any questioning of the company’s objectives or functions is therefore erroneous.

Starting from this premise, we analyze the contractual relationship between the shareholders, considered as the owners of the company, and the “agents”, i.e. the managers hired by the shareholders to manage it. Clearly, the latter know the company much better than the former, and may therefore have different interests from those of the shareholders.

One of the key challenges will therefore be to find mechanisms for aligning the interests of agents with those of shareholders. Corporate governance is thus conceived as a means of “disciplining” the manager by encouraging him to act in the shareholder’s interest, and sanctioning him if he fails to do so.

When academic theory transforms business practices

These theses found a strong echo in academic circles.

On the one hand, the image of “scientific rigor” brought by economics has exerted a strong attraction on corporate law circles. Such is the case, for example, of the “Law and Economics” movement, which aims to apply the methods and postulates of economic analysis to the institutions of the legal system (contracts, property rights, criminal sanctions, etc.). On the other hand, economists have embarked on the production of countless empirical studies testing the relationship between share price (considered as the indicator measuring corporate performance) and other variables (board structure, capitalization, mergers) to discover the keys to “good corporate governance”.

Academic theses on the pre-eminence of shareholder value served as a basis for the corporate governance movement.

This has manifested itself in the development and adoption of corporate law reforms designed to increase shareholder rights and/or limit the power of management. Over the past few decades, a number of regulations in the United States and Europe have been designed to encourage managers to focus on shareholder value.

The same applies to all mechanisms designed to encourage the linking of executive remuneration to the share price (variable portion in addition to the fixed portion, stock options). This is also one of the underlying objectives in the development of international accounting rules, with the growing importance of “fair value” accounting for large listed companies.

Finally, it is above all in business circles themselves that the idea of the company as being first and foremost at the service of its shareholders has gradually taken hold.

In financial circles, this discourse has found all the more resonance as it has developed at the same time as the liberalization of financial markets. Hedge funds and institutional investors (such as pension funds, insurance companies and sovereign wealth funds) alike are developing a short-termist rationale, even though they are supposed to be looking to the long term.

In large listed companies, executives themselves are gradually putting in place, in agreement with boards of directors, mechanisms designed to align the interests of management with those of shareholders: remuneration policy, distribution of stock options, reduction in the independence of boards of directors (with, for example, the retreat of staggered-term boards, which made hostile takeovers more difficult). 8 . The case of Carlos Tavares, CEO of Stellantis, is typical. Of the 36 million he will receive in remuneration by 2023, his fixed salary will account for just 2 million, the rest being made up of bonuses and share-based bonuses. 9

This has also led to the development of practices aimed at carrying out massive share buybacks (to boost the share price. All in all, as noted inEssentiel 6 on corporate financing, we may well wonder whether the shareholders of listed companies are still really financing them, or whether the stock market has become nothing more than a big machine for extracting value from the company.

These measures, which affect governance, have very concrete consequences in operational terms, with the multiplication of short-termist measures (outsourcing of jobs, reduced investment and R&D).

The company is not owned by its shareholders

As we saw inEssentials 1, joint-stock companies are legal entities with their own legal personality. As such, they are nobody’s property: they hold assets, enter into contracts and may commit offences in their own name.

Shareholders are the owners of shares, which gives them limited rights: a Renault shareholder can vote at the Annual General Meeting (AGM) to elect a Board of Directors; he or she can receive dividends if it has been decided to distribute them during the AGM. But he does not own the factories or the car inventory (even in proportion to his shareholding). From a legal point of view, shareholders are not so different from other creditors, suppliers or employees. They all have a contractual relationship with the company. None is the “owner” of the company itself.

The case of the United States

This idea has no legal basis. As Lynn A. Stout 10 for the United States, the birthplace of Friedmanian ideology. According to the Delaware Corporation Code, where the majority of Fortune 500 companies are incorporated, “a corporation may be incorporated or organized under this section to carry on or promote any lawful business or purpose”. 11

Its primary purpose is not to serve its shareholders. It would, however, be possible to write into the company’s articles of association that its purpose is to maximize shareholder value, but virtually no company does this.

The absence of a legal objective to maximize shareholder value is also validated by case law, the main source of law in the United States.

The Business Judgment Rule, a legal doctrine that exists in almost all common law countries common law 12 is designed to protect executives (directors or employees) from lawsuits arising from their management decisions. It establishes 13 that as long as they have acted in good faith, with sufficient information and without conflicts of interest, the courts need not question the validity of their decision as to what is best for the company (and this, even when the decisions turned out to be commercially negative). In the United States, many judgments invoking this doctrine state that “outside a limited set of circumstances as defined by the Revlon decision” 14 a board of directors, while always required to act in an informed manner, does not have a duty per se to maximize shareholder value in the short term, even in the context of a takeover bid”. 15

The case of France

According to article 1832 of the French Civil Code , “A partnership is formed by two or more persons who agree by contract to allocate property or their industry to a common enterprise, with a view to sharing the profits or benefiting from the savings that may result”, and until 2019, article 1833 was limited to the fact that “all partnerships must have a lawful object and be formed in the common interest of the partners”.

These two articles, which make the profit to be shared between the associates (the shareholders) the purpose of the company, have been much debated and have been the subject of proposals for substantial amendments. 16 particularly in the discussions leading up to the 2019 Loi Pacte.

While the latter did not modify article 1832, and thus the purpose of the company, which remains to make a profit, it did add the following provision to article 1833: “The company shall be managed in its corporate interest, taking into consideration the social and environmental stakes of its activity.” The notion of “social interest” is an interesting one: it highlights the fact that it concerns the interest of the legal entity itself, which may be distinct from that of its shareholders. In addition, the question of social and environmental issues has been introduced.

Shareholder value doesn’t exist!

The notion of value creation is vague and misleading

The ideology that management should only be interested in “shareholder value” has succeeded in imposing a confusing expression on business circles: “value creation”.

On the one hand, this is tantamount to confusing value with money, whereas this notion refers to moral (values) and human (social or ecological utility of the company) categories that go far beyond the purely pecuniary dimension. In the module on accounting, we explain how accounting vocabulary (profit, value, cost), far from being neutral, structures our vision of the economy.

On the other hand, it limits this monetary value to the enrichment of the shareholder (through the distribution of dividends or an increase in the value of the shares held). Yet the value (in the monetary sense) created by the company is distributed far beyond the company itself. As we saw inEssentiel 5 on the damaging effects of the ideology of maximizing shareholder value, the value created by a company is much more a question of sales than profit: it is therefore shared between all stakeholders (suppliers and service providers, employees, the public purse via taxes and social security contributions, shareholders via dividends, bankers where applicable, and finally the company itself via investment and development).

Not one, but many shareholders with different needs and concerns

As Lynn A. Stout, “shareholder is a fictitious term”. 10

The models used by economists promoting shareholder value presuppose the existence of a homogenous, clearly identified entity, driven solely by the desire to maximize its utility (via share price increases). Of course, such an entity does not exist.

Shareholders are people (legal entities or individuals) whose needs and concerns differ according to their investment horizon, the degree of diversification of their portfolio, and their interest in other types of financial assets. They may also have different views on ethics and corporate social responsibility. So, there’s nothing in common between: the manager of a hedge fund who seeks to maximize returns in the very short term and renews the assets in his portfolio several times a year; the manager of a pension fund who needs to generate regular, long-term returns; or the individual investor, concerned that his money should not finance global warming.

As Lynn A. Stout: “The ideology of shareholder value focuses on the interests of a narrow subset of shareholders, those who are the most short-sighted, the most opportunistic, the most willing to impose external costs and the most indifferent to ethics and the welfare of others.”10 As we explained in theEssentiel 5 This ideology has very concrete consequences: it leads managers to focus on short-term results, sacrificing long-term issues such as the environment, employee well-being, and sometimes even the viability of the company itself.

Corporate competitiveness as an end in itself

A company’s competitiveness is its ability to withstand international competition. To what extent is it capable of selling and supplying one or more goods or services on a given market in a competitive situation? Competitiveness is assessed through the dynamics of a company’s market share.

A distinction is usually made between :

  • Price competitiveness is based on the difference between a company’s selling price and that of its competitors, and therefore depends on the company’s costs (labor, purchasing, financing costs, etc.) in a given economy;
  • and non-price competitiveness, which is based on innovation, productivity and quality improvement, enabling a “move upmarket” and therefore a rise in selling price.

Competitiveness challenges vary according to context

In a situation of fair competition (all competitors are subject to the same regulations, taxes and duties, as well as equivalent access to raw materials, services and infrastructures, etc.), competitiveness depends mainly on the decisions taken by the company, in the areas where it has control: the choice of its products and services, their quality, its recruitment, its communication strategy, the quality of its after-sales service, etc.

In a monopoly situation, the company doesn’t need to be competitive; in our economies, however, it is still obliged to offer a minimum price-quality ratio, because alternative offers usually end up developing or because pressure from citizens becomes too strong.

Companies exposed to international competition are in a different situation, generally one of asymmetrical competition. A company may face competition in its own country from imports from foreign companies benefiting from regulatory, fiscal, social or monetary advantages. It may also try to export to a country where its competitors benefit from such advantages.

Let’s take a few examples from French companies, which can easily be generalized.

  • French trucking companies face competition from foreign European companies who can bring their“seconded” employees to work in France, paying social security contributions in their country of origin that may be much lower than in France.
  • Agricultural companies whose production in France is subject to environmental standards, while their foreign competitors can export products where standards are less stringent (or even non-existent).
  • Companies subject to the EuropeanCO2 quota market (the ETS), competing with companies that pay no costs for theCO2 they emit during production and, as in the previous case, are subject to fewer environmental constraints.
  • Companies competing with producers based in low-wage and/or undervalued-currency countries (this has long been the case with Japan, the “Asian dragons ” and, of course, China). In both cases, these companies are able to export to the French market at lower prices than French producers (lower wage costs; lower selling prices due to the exchange rate).
  • Companies in competition with others which, thanks to the size of their domestic market, have been able to make massive technological or industrial investments (as in the digital sector and the GAFAMs).

Faced with these forms of environmental, social or monetary dumping, and without a public policy aimed at rebalancing this competition, it is very difficult for companies to resist, except in specific “niches” by managing to differentiate themselves very skilfully. But it’s a gamble that’s hard to sustain over the long term.

It’s hardly surprising that France has undergone severe deindustrialization over the past 40 years. The state has not sought to rebalance competition, believing it to be beneficial to consumers. As a result, companies have either disappeared or adapted by concentrating or relocating production to low-cost countries (facilitated by lower international freight costs and the liberalization of capital movements). France has nevertheless specialized in a few major sectors: luxury goods, cosmetics, pharmaceuticals, the transport industry (space, aeronautics, automobiles, railways), tourism, agriculture and agri-food.

To justify these abandonments, economists generally invoke the theory of comparative advantage: no country should struggle in sectors where its companies are relatively less competitive, and should aim to specialize where they have advantages. This theory does not stand up to analysis. Firstly, because international trade is not guided by international goals of economic efficiency, but rather by issues of domination. Secondly, in such a context, a country can weaken on all fronts. And last but not least, because the cost of such competition is clearly ecological and social. Inequalities worldwide and within each country have increased, and the ecological crisis has almost spiraled out of control.

A nation’s competitiveness: a vague notion and a dangerous goal

Faced with the difficulties encountered by companies in the face of international competition, some argue that the country’s economy as a whole must be competitive. If social charges, taxes and salaries are too high for exporting companies, they must be lowered, even if this means reducing the quality and role of public services or national solidarity schemes.

It’s the notion of “competitiveness of a nation” that we’re going to see is debatable, even meaningless, as economist Paul Krugman puts it. 19 . Let’s take Germany as an example.

Germany sought to increase its competitiveness with the Hartz laws between 2003 and 2005, by reforming the labor code. German exporters benefited from a double advantage: lower labor costs and greater labor flexibility, in addition to access to Eastern European countries with low-cost labor, newly accessible since the fall of the Berlin Wall. For many years, this strategy benefited Germany, to the detriment of its European partners. It resulted in massive trade surpluses. But has it benefited the German population? The rising poverty rate and falling unemployment rate suggest otherwise.

The Covid crisis, the war in Ukraine and the economic war with Russia have shown us the futility of such policies. A return to common-sense notions such as economic and energy sovereignty shows that the absence of such considerations leads to major risks for a country’s “social well-being”: health, energy autonomy and, more generally, its ability to control the production or supply of goods and services considered essential.

Reconciling competitiveness and the good life?

We need companies and the dynamism they bring to economic life. Some of them face international competition, which is inevitable in a complex, technological world.

On the other hand, it is not desirable for companies to be subjected to the violence of unprotected markets. This “law of the markets” is quite simply the law of the strongest. Is it in a nation’s interest for some of “its” companies to be eliminated because they are less economically efficient than their competitors in another country? This is debatable, especially when a nation’s sovereignty or its citizens’ access to essential goods and services such as food, energy or medicines are at stake; or when jobs are lost to other countries. International competition drives down costs, and therefore the prices paid by consumers. But the citizen (who is also a producer and can become unemployed) doesn’t always understand this, and may agree to pay more as a consumer for greater autonomy or jobs.

Is it possible to protect certain companies or sectors from this market violence? Yes, of course, unless we submit to a doxa that would make free trade an absolute good.

To begin with, in social and environmental matters, the State must ensure that it applies “mirror measures”. 20 which re-establish the balance of competition between companies from all countries selling products on our territory. This can be achieved through the negotiation of bilateral trade treaties, which are currently replacing multilateral treaties, which have been less in vogue for years. At a deeper level, public authorities (European and French) can and must define “industrial” policies that identify strategic sectors where companies need to be helped and, if necessary, supported. These policies must take into account the vital issues of access to raw materials, energy and natural resources. It must aim to implement a circular economy.

The development of Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) would be enough to reduce the negative impacts of companies.

Since the turn of the twentieth century, the notion of corporate social responsibility (CSR) has become an indispensable tool for addressing the impact of business on people and the environment. After tracing the history of CSR and outlining its practical implications for companies, we will show that, despite its appeal, it remains a peripheral, non-structural area of business.

The theoretical and academic origins of CSR

While concerns about the impact of business emerged with the emergence of big business itself in the late 19th century, the notion of CSR is generally credited to economist Howard Bowen, who responded in Social responsibilities of the businessman (1953) to questions raised by American Protestant churches about business ethics and the responsibility of the entrepreneur. According to Bowen, business leaders must integrate into their decisions, on a voluntary basis, the economic and social values and objectives supported by society. He emphasized the role of pressure from civil society and the market in making this social responsibility a reality. The following decades were marked by academic debates on the definition of the concept, notably with the work of Keith Davis and Archie Carroll, and by the arrival of new ideas such as stakeholder theory in the 1980s. 21

From the late 1970s onwards, the concept of CSR was hotly contested by Chicago School economists 6 . A company’s sole responsibility would be to maximize shareholder value. The idea of CSR was inept, even dangerous.

Few developments could so profoundly undermine the very foundations of our free society as the acceptance by corporate executives of a social responsibility other than that of making as much money as possible for their shareholders. It’s a fundamentally subversive doctrine. If businessmen have a responsibility other than that of maximum profit for shareholders, how can they know what it is? Can self-appointed private individuals decide what is in society’s interest?

Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom, 1962

Putting CSR into practice begins with approaches based on voluntary commitment on the part of companies.

At the end of the 20th century, with growing awareness of ecological issues and the impact of large corporations, CSR began to take on a more concrete form.

The publication in 1987 of the Brundtland Report, Our Common Future 23 established the concept of sustainable development, defined as “development that meets the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs”. Increasingly, CSR is seen as a corporate contribution to the challenges of sustainable development, broken down into 17 major objectives since 2015.

Sustainable Development Goals

In September 2015, the United Nations General Assembly approved the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development. This is broken down into 17 Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs), assessed by means of 169 targets and 231 indicators. The SDGs are often used as a reference for CSR reports produced by companies.

sustainable-development-goal

Source The Global Goals

Voluntary approaches are proposed to companies by international organizations such as the OECD and the UN (see box), as well as by private initiatives. Most often, these take the form of codes, pacts or charters to which companies adhere and for which they are subsequently held accountable. They can also take the form of reference frameworks that can then be used to obtain certification or a label.

Some major international standards

The OECD Guidelines for Multinational Enterprises were first published in 1976. In the 2023 edition, they are presented as “recommendations”. 24 “that governments jointly address to multinational enterprises with a view to improving their contribution to sustainable development and addressing the negative impacts associated with their activities on individuals, the planet and society”.

The Global Compact is a United Nations initiative launched in 2000.

Adhering companies must draw up an annual communication showing how they comply with the 10 principles (relating in particular to human rights, the environment and anti-corruption) of the Compact, as well as their contribution to the sustainable development goals adopted by the UN General Assembly in 2015.

ISO 26000, published in 2010, is intended for companies and organizations committed to operating in a socially responsible manner. It provides guidelines to help organizations apply the concepts of sustainable development to six major themes. 25

These initiatives may concern a particular sector (from which they most often originate).

For example, the Responsible Care initiative, launched in 1984 by Canada’s chemical industry, is now the sector’s global CSR initiative. By signing the Responsible Care Global Charter, a chemical company commits to implementing six key sustainability principles aimed at “managing chemicals safely throughout their life cycle, promoting their role in improving quality of life and contributing to sustainable development”. The various trade federations offer management tools to implement the Charter’s key principles. According to the International Council of Chemical Associations, by March 2024, it had been signed by 580 of the world’s chemical manufacturing companies, representing a total of 96% of the world’s largest chemical companies.

Among all these initiatives, the finance sector occupies a special place.

In fact, as well as being the target of CSR initiatives in the same way as any other company, this sector is also the driving force behind a growing demand for ESG (environmental, social and governance) reporting for all other companies.

Launched in 2006 by UN Secretary-General Kofi Annan, the Principles for Responsible Investment were drawn up by an international group of institutional investors to provide a repertoire of actions to be implemented on a voluntary basis with a view to integrating ESG criteria into investment practices. The signatories (nearly 5,400 by March 2023 26 ) are required to report annually on their responsible investment practices.

The Equator Principles, the first version of which dates back to 2003, are the benchmark for project financing by financial institutions (mainly banks). By signing them, an institution undertakes to take into account a certain number of social and environmental evaluation criteria when selecting projects for financing. The initiative had 128 signatory institutions by March 2024.

The development of extra-financial reporting and ESG indicators

Non-financial reporting consists of companies reporting on their impact through ESG indicators, i.e. indicators relating to the environment, social and societal aspects, and corporate governance.

As we saw inEssentiel 8, this demand for reporting was initiated by private players, particularly investors, or civil society organizations (such as the Global Reporting Initiative). The second stage in the development of reporting regulations was in France (from the NRE law of 2001 onwards), and then in Europe. Then, faced with the proliferation of different labels, standards and benchmarks, the European Union decided to promulgate a regulation for financial players (the SFRD), followed by a directive aimed at standardizing the practices of European companies operating on the continent (the CSRD). In response, Anglo-Saxon private-sector players also began to draw up competing international standards, within the IFRS Foundation (or, to be more precise, the International Sustainability Standards Board (ISSB)).

It’s worth noting that the notions of CSR and ESG are often considered interchangeable, which is unfortunate. This is tantamount to equating the implementation of a policy with its measurement. 27

To find out more, seeEssentiel 8.2 on extra-financial reporting andidée reçue 5 on ESG indicators.

The development of a more restrictive regulatory framework

While the voluntary approach to CSR remains dominant, the last decade has seen a shift in emphasis, as evidenced by the evolution of the European definition.

In 2001, the European Commission adopted a Green Paper 28 a definition of CSR as “the voluntary integration of social and environmental concerns by companies into their commercial activities and their relations with their stakeholders”.

In 2011, it goes one step further. CSR is now defined as “the responsibility of companies for the effects they have on society”; taking responsibility means engaging with stakeholders “in a process designed to integrate social, environmental, ethical, human rights and consumer concerns into their core business activities and strategy”. 29

We are thus moving from a purely voluntarist logic to a vision that goes to the heart of the company’s business. The notion of voluntary action is replaced by that of impact control.

In its 2011 Communication, the Commission also states that CSR standards can besoft law, but can also behard law: “public authorities should have a supportive role through an intelligent combination of voluntary policy measures and, where appropriate, complementary regulatory provisions.”

Without claiming to be exhaustive, let’s attempt to identify a typology of the various “CSR measures” taken by public authorities:

  • measures encouraging or requiring extra-financial reporting ;
  • compliance with international human rights standards and related prohibitions (child labor, forced labor, etc.);
  • regulation (via emissions standards for cars, for example, or the energy performance of buildings), or even the banning of certain activities deemed too polluting (for example, in France, the various laws aimed at banning single-use plastic objects; the banning of chemical substances or materials hazardous to health, such as asbestos or PFAS; or to the environment, such as CFCs, responsible for the “hole in the ozone layer”, etc.);
  • measures aimed at limiting the management impacts of companies in all sectors, such as the tertiary sector decree (mandatory energy renovation of tertiary buildings) or the law on the orientation of mobility (2019), which includes various measures aimed at reducing the use of cars in companies or electrifying their fleets.
  • measures to encourage the emergence of companies with a corporate purpose that goes beyond the sole pursuit of profit (such as the PACTE law in France, seeEssentiel 4.4)
  • measures to increase the responsibility of multinational companies, particularly with regard to the actions of their suppliers and subcontractors.

CSR remains a peripheral business area

Since the 1990s, CSR has led to a number of developments in companies

In companies of a certain size (ETI or large corporations), sustainable development or CSR manager positions (sometimes with dedicated teams, sometimes with correspondents in other departments) have been created; professional associations have also emerged, such as C3D in France.

These teams are in charge of responding to requests for extra-financial reporting from investors or regulatory obligations, producing the sustainable development report and, if necessary, leading the philanthropic policy, conducting reflections on the company’s sustainability strategies, improving processes and so on.

Despite these encouraging developments, it has to be said that profit remains the overriding objective.

As lawyer Daniel Hurstel notes, “CSR only marginally affects the current business model”. For him, it “can be described as ‘peripheral‘”. Indeed, at its best, it rectifies, influences and corrects the way a company operates, but it does not call into question its purpose, nor the social organization that stems from it. It is part of a vision in which the interactions of the business with its environment are still apprehended as areas of risk that can generate costs.” 30

According to philosopher Cécile Renouard, CSR should be considered holistically, covering all aspects of corporate life: the social utility of the product, governance and value-sharing, the technical model of production, the accounting and fiscal dimension, working conditions, the impact on common goods and the local community. All too often, however, it is confined to marginal improvements to processes, or to a logic of the lesser evil (if we don’t do it, others will, taking less care than we do). It is often limited to highlighting one-off good practices at operational level, or philanthropic activities unrelated to the business.

The company’s various responsibilities

corporate-social-responsibility

Source Cécile Renouard, Éthique et entreprise, Éditions de l’Atelier, 2015

Corporate social responsibility and shareholder irresponsibility

In an enlightening article, economist Guillaume Vuillemey poses a question that is rarely raised in the CSR debate: “Isn’t social responsibility doomed to be an empty word when the individuals who own, manage and derive the profits from a company themselves enjoy very limited responsibility?” 31

Indeed, a company’s shareholders benefit from limited liability: they cannot be held financially responsible for a company’s actions to an amount greater than their initial investment.

This state of affairs only became widespread in the second half of the 19th century. Previously, shareholders were financially liable for a company’s actions far beyond their initial capital contribution 32 . The justification for this limited liability was that the many small shareholders would be too far removed from the management of the company and would have too little power to be held responsible for its activities. What is understandable in the case of diffuse shareholding is much less so in the case of shareholders controlling the majority of the capital, especially in the case of parent companies in relation to their subsidiaries.

For Guillaume Vuillemey, this limited liability is the source of numerous perverse effects, not only for the company’s creditors (in the event of excessive risk-taking by shareholders), but also and above all for society as a whole. It allows the privatization of profits, which benefit shareholders, and the socialization of costs, such as ecological damage caused by economic activity.

CSR does not seem to him to be a satisfactory alternative, because it is based on an essentially abstract vision of responsibility: it is “a responsibility in the absolute, unlimited, which makes no reference to any particular place or to any concrete damage”. 31 Shareholder liability, on the other hand, is based on the traditional understanding of the term: liability for something concrete (debts, specific damage).

CSR can therefore only be a very imperfect counterweight to the excesses of irresponsible shareholders, especially as the concept itself is not free from the risk of excesses.

The risks of CSR drift

For Guillaume Vuillemey, “Corporate ‘social responsibility’ is an intrinsically abstract and vague concept, which leaves room for serious abuse”. 31 It can become a selling point (and thus ultimately a profit maximizer for shareholders). CSR managers are thus often called upon to justify the importance of their function and the costs it generates (salary and other), by attempting to demonstrate their contribution to the company’s profitability (improved detection and therefore risk management, ability to anticipate certain societal trends useful in terms of marketing and image). This is obviously a problematic confusion of genres.

CSR can also be used to promote the idea that self-discipline is sufficient and regulation optional.

It raises questions in terms of the hierarchy of values, which is left to the discretion of companies (who may choose to emphasize certain good practices to the detriment of others).

These abuses are all the more pronounced because CSR and ESG reporting are often confused. However, as we shall see in the following misconception, a good ESG rating in no way presumes a company’s strategy.

So, despite its appeal, corporate social responsibility appears to be largely insufficient to truly reorient the activities of companies, especially the largest ones. As Daniel Hurstel notes, “profits and social issues should […] be based on comparable forces – managers would then have to arbitrate, or even anticipate, any conflict, with a view to finding a balance”. 30 To achieve this, a number of changes are needed: we have already mentioned legal changes, such as the re-establishment of shareholder liability (at least for the largest shareholders), or the introduction of a duty of vigilance. We could also mention developments in accounting, regulatory and tax tools, etc.

Good ESG ratings are a guarantee of ethics and financial performance

As we saw in the previous preconceived notion, since the 1990s, large companies in France and Europe have been moving towards sustainable development and CSR, i.e., integrating social and environmental issues into their thinking, and even their strategy, at least in poster form.

This trend has been accompanied by a growing demand for extra-financial reporting on the part of investors, or to meet regulatory obligations, especially in France and the European Union (find out more inEssentiel 8.2 on extra-financial reporting).

This reporting consists of evaluating and then disclosing information on the company’s impacts via so-called “ESG” indicators. G for governance complements E for environment and S for social, the idea being that these three areas are in fact interdependent. It is carried out by sustainable development or CSR managers. The main indicators are communicated in annual reports, which also highlight companies’ progress and best practices in these three areas.

Social and environmental rating” or “extra-financial rating” agencies (for simplicity’s sake, we’ll call them ESG in the following) have been set up in France. 36 Europe and the United States to assess these practices externally, in the same way that financial agencies assess the financial robustness of companies. They analyze company reports and communications, request additional information where necessary, and assign “ESG ratings” according to their own methodologies (and thus weightings between the various criteria).

Responsible investment labels (such as the SRI label in France) have also been developed to help investors direct their savings towards funds that base their investment strategy on extra-financial criteria in addition to traditional financial indicators.

ESG ratings and environmental impact indicators: two very different, even opposing, approaches

ESG rating was born in the world of… rating, with the aim of assessing a company’s performance as quantitatively as possible, in areas not covered by financial rating. This approach must be distinguished from those developed in the 1990s (Life Cycle Assessment), and in the 2000s for the climate, with the carbon footprint. Although these assessment tools are now used by companies in their ESG reporting, it is useful to understand how these approaches are fundamentally different, which we will illustrate with the carbon footprint.

The aim of the carbon footprint is to assess a company’s direct and indirect greenhouse gas emissions and, at the same time, its “dependence” on these emissions: if they are reduced by regulatory obligation or for other reasons, what can the company do? The aim of this approach is not, a priori, to demonstrate performance, but rather to make managers aware of the risks involved.

There are two clear differences with the ESG approach:

  • estimates are made in order of magnitude to help decision-making. They are therefore steering tools, not reporting tools.
  • they are not intended to form part of an overall rating, where the various aspects of sustainability are weighted as determined by the rating agency.

When the financial community took up the carbon footprint tool, the difference in approach was very clear. In 2015, following COP21 in Paris, asset managers like Amundi in France wanted to know the “carbon weight” of their portfolios, with a view to ESG communication with their investors and stakeholders. To this end, they have limited the measurement of carbon weight to direct emissions (SCOPE1). From the point of view of a carbon balance approach, this is almost pointless: for the vast majority of companies, the most important and significant item is upstream and downstream indirect emissions (SCOPE3). Limiting ourselves to Scope 1 means remaining largely blind to the risks that the carbon footprint is supposed to reveal.

To find out more about the carbon footprint and understand what is covered by scopes 1, 2 and 3, see our sheet Counting GHG emissions.

There’s no doubt that the move to take ecological and social issues into account is a step in the right direction.

However, it is important to remember two pitfalls.

A company with a good ESG rating may have questionable or even reprehensible social or environmental practices.

The media regularly reveal scandals (such as the ORPEA scandal in 2022 37 and Ehpad) or significant anomalies involving companies rated highly by ESG rating agencies.

The case of Total is emblematic: this company has very good ESG ratings, which does not prevent it from developing EACOP in Africa. 38 a project that is disastrous for the environment, displaced local populations and the climate.

There are three main reasons for this:

  • ESG indicators do not cover all areas of business ethics. We will confine ourselves here to the question of taxation. Is it possible to be exemplary and yet have abusive tax optimization practices? Yet CSR managers do not cover this area, which is reserved for the CFO or the tax director. And some companies can be rated highly in terms of CSR, but still have abusive tax practices.
  • ESG rating is by no means an exact science, and in practice is particularly complex. The data to be analyzed can be difficult to access, hard to synthesize and sometimes subjective. If it were a question of verifying compliance with social and environmental legislation, it would not be so easy, given the complexity of the subject. But in general, the aim is to go further. Solid analysis is expensive, and buyers of extra-financial data are not prepared to pay the price.
  • There is always a question of arbitration between criteria – or aggregation of criteria – which are very numerous in the construction of a rating. As with financial ratings, players (especially financial players) demand synthetic ratings. This raises formidable problems of aggregation. Should the scores obtained on each criterion be averaged? In this case, a poor score on an environmental criterion, for example, may be offset by a good score on another relating to the company’s pay policy or corporate governance. Should a geometric average be calculated, giving more weight to poor scores? Should minimum scores be required for all criteria?

ESG best practices cannot be justified on the grounds of better financial performance

Sustainable development and CSR managers are generally under a great deal of pressure from senior management, the finance department and, more generally, their colleagues. The nagging question is: how can CSR-related expenditure or investment contribute to the company’s performance? Aren’t they just costs with no value or counterpart?

The question is inescapable, if not legitimate, given that companies are supposed to “create value” (for their shareholders), and that they cultivate a sense of performance, “cost-cutting” practices and, symmetrically, permanent choices of initiatives (commercial or industrial marketing) likely to increase the company’s profits.

Numerous studies attempt to answer this question, and CSR ambassadors (both inside and outside the company) generally want the answer to be positive. The argument generally put forward is that the development of a CSR practice within a company improves management’s information, their perception of medium- and long-term risks, and the expectations of stakeholders (including customers and shareholders), which are not limited to financial considerations.

As for academic studies on the links between financial performance and CSR, they are the subject of much debate. Let’s take the most emblematic case.

In 2023, economist Andrew King critically analyzed 39 of one of the most cited studies 40 in the world, aimed at proving that companies most committed to “sustainability” perform better financially than their “low sustainability” counterparts. It shows that these conclusions pose major problems of interpretation and sampling choice. The debate is an old one. In a 2008 article, “CSR and/or financial performance: benchmarks and avenues for research”, economists Jean-Pierre Ponssard and Patricia Crifo concluded that studies “do not yet lead to any consensus”.

There are several possible explanations for this phenomenon.

Firstly, these analyses are based on small samples, with too short a time horizon to control for biases in terms of risk, company size, or sectors represented in SRI portfolios and indices, for example. What’s more, the variables vary widely from one study to the next, limiting the relevance of the comparisons made. 41 . For Margolis and Walsh (2001) 42 for example, out of 95 articles on the links between CSR and financial performance, we can identify 70 different ways of measuring performance and 27 different samples.

Then, as Aurélien Acquier explains 43 “The majority of academic work – aimed at attempting to link ESG and financial performance – relies on ESG as a proxy, aggregating numerous parameters.”

“ESG allows us to 1) measure a company’s transparency on a set of extra-financial risks and 2) position their efforts in relation to their peers, and as a result, can be taken as a signal of reputation in the sector.”

“But there’s no direct link between this measure and a trajectory for reducing the firm’s ecological impact (or the scale of investment required to achieve it), and that’s the whole problem in relation to the original question.”

Finally, the question is in fact badly put, for two main reasons.

  1. The logic of “CSR” performance is not aligned a priori with financial logic. They are two distinct fields. To take a caricatural example, a company that sells outdated products will necessarily end up “losing money”, whatever its internal management or environmental practices. CSR does absolutely nothing to raise awareness of this obsolescence.

Conversely, managers of financially successful companies may behave in an “inhumane” way, or sell products that destroy the environment or are hazardous to health.

  1. For companies with strong financial return requirements, which are necessarily short-termist, “financial” is more decisive than CSR.

In practice, in these companies, the CSR manager does not report to the CFO.

Social and environmental standards and regulations would be obstacles to entrepreneurial freedom

First of all, it should be remembered that freedom of enterprise is considered a constitutional right in France. 44 and is part of the European Charter of Fundamental Rights (art. 16). Moreover, case law on entrepreneurial freedom has fluctuated over the last twenty years.

Whatever its constitutional status, it is clear that, like any freedom, entrepreneurial freedom cannot be absolute. It is framed by legal rules and, more profoundly, by the culture in which the company operates. On this point, it’s worth noting that establishing a framework cannot be seen as a brake on entrepreneurial freedom, since it mainly consists in setting the rules of the game common to all. It helps avoid the law of the strong, and can be a source of creativity.

On the one hand, companies regularly call for environmental and social regulations to be relaxed and simplified, and for taxes and social security contributions to be cut, which would reduce their profitability. On the other hand, they use natural resources and energy, and benefit from a healthy environment and well-trained staff in good physical and mental health. Their demand is therefore akin to “free rider” behavior: they want to enjoy an advantage without paying the price.

It is therefore up to the public authorities, guarantors of the general interest and justice, to put in place the appropriate measures to limit the temptations and, in any case, the extent of the harm caused by companies’ activities to people and the environment. The range of tools available in this area is well known: regulations or even bans, taxation, infrastructure development, general information, and above all, setting a course and a roadmap.

The precautionary principle is an obstacle to progress

The impact of human activities on nature is considerable(see our module on resources and pollution) and sometimes poorly understood. For example, the majority of chemical molecules have been created and distributed without exhaustive knowledge of their effects on the environment, on living beings or on human health.

It is often assumed that risks are unavoidable (as the saying goes, “you can’t make an omelette without breaking some eggs”), and that they are worth taking if the “cost-benefit” balance is positive. Without getting into the debate about the relevance of cost-benefit analysis, let’s just say that this tool can only be used for impacts “at the margin” of a given system. At best, it can be used to make comparisons between projects (or between clearly defined situations).

The precautionary principle was formulated precisely to deal with situations where the risks are potentially very great, but where scientific knowledge is insufficient. As we shall see, despite strong criticism that it would block scientific progress and innovation, it is clear that it is still very rarely applied.

The origins of the precautionary principle

Since the beginning of the industrial era, there have been numerous examples of manufacturers bringing new products to market whose impact on the environment or human health, uncertain given the state of knowledge at the time, has subsequently proved to be serious and irreversible. The report Early Warning, Late Lessons, published by the European Environment Agency in 2001, documents numerous examples of this.

Asbestos (insulation and fireproofing), lead (anti-knock agent in gasoline), DDT (pesticide), PCBs (dielectrics) and benzene (solvent) have all been shown to cause cancer.

Other examples include CFCs (used as propellants or in the cold chain), which are responsible for stratospheric ozone depletion (commonly referred to as the “ozone hole”), and DES (diethylstilbestrol), used in particular as a menopause regulator, which has been shown to be a powerful endocrine disruptor.

Processes intended to generate substantial savings have turned out to be extremely harmful to human health or the environment, without these effects having been anticipated. Such is the case of animal meal used to feed cattle, which was at the root of the “mad cow crisis”.

Practices such as the overfishing of cod in Newfoundland have proved harmful, whether for the environment, society or the economy itself: cod has disappeared from Newfoundland.

All these health and environmental scandals led to the formulation of the precautionary principle at the Earth Summit in Rio in 1992, and several countries have now enshrined it in national law (see box). The idea behind this principle is to dispel any doubts that may exist about the harmfulness of a product, process or technology, before authorizing it.

To protect the environment, precautionary measures must be widely applied by states according to their capabilities. Where there are threats of serious or irreversible damage, lack of full scientific certainty shall not be used as a reason for postponing cost-effective measures to prevent environmental degradation.

Principle 15 of the Rio Declaration on Environment and Development, 1992

The precautionary principle in France and the European Union

Since the 1992 Maastricht Treaty, the precautionary principle has been enshrined in European law, according to which EU environmental policy is “based on the precautionary principle and on the principles that preventive action should be taken, that environmental damage should as a priority be rectified at source and that the polluter should pay”. 45 In 2000, in its Communication on recourse to the precautionary principle, the Commission made it clear that the precautionary principle is not limited to environmental issues, and explained how it can be applied.

In France, it was the 1995 Barnier Law on the reinforcement of environmental protection that introduced into law “the precautionary principle, according to which the absence of certainty, given current scientific and technical knowledge, must not delay the adoption of effective and proportionate measures aimed at preventing a risk of serious and irreversible damage to the environment at an economically acceptable cost”. 46 France has thus toned down the Rio definition by adding the notions of “proportionate” reaction and “economically acceptable cost”. In 2004, the precautionary principle was incorporated into the French Environment Charter, which stipulates that, faced with a situation that falls within the scope of the precautionary principle (scientific uncertainty and risk of serious and irreversible damage), public authorities must ensure “the implementation of risk assessment procedures and the adoption of provisional and proportionate measures to prevent damage from occurring”. It thus becomes a principle of action leading to the development of scientific research. In 2005, it took on constitutional status when the Charter was incorporated into the French constitution.

The precautionary principle is recognized in many other countries, including Belgium, the Netherlands, Germany, Sweden, Canada and Brazil.

The precautionary principle is widely criticized, particularly in economic and industrial circles.

It is criticized for opposing scientific progress and innovation. It is often presented in a caricatured way: to avoid all risk, nothing could be done. This is, for example, the position adopted in the report of the Attali Commission for the liberation of green growth (2008), which recommends removing the principle from the constitutional bloc.

To counter the precautionary principle, the idea has arisen to counterbalance or even replace it with an “innovation principle”. In France, at the end of 2014, several deputies tabled a constitutional bill (not adopted) aimed at substituting a “responsible innovation principle” for the precautionary principle in the Charter of the Environment 47 . At European level, a similar initiative took place and was, itself, crowned with success. The “innovation principle”, lacking a legal basis (or even a definition), was introduced into the texts surrounding the creation of the “Horizon Europe” framework program for research and innovation. 48 . This principle was invented and promoted to the European authorities by the European Risk Forum, a lobbying organization whose members come mainly from the chemical, oil and tobacco sectors. The aim is: “Whenever political or regulatory decisions are under consideration, the impact on innovation should be assessed and taken into account.” 49 Civil society players, including the NGO Corporate Europe Observatory, which carried out an in-depth survey of ERF’s involvement in this area. 50 s involvement, fear that this principle, presented in a consensual manner, could be used as a legal basis to counterbalance, or even render ineffective, the precautionary principle.

The precautionary principle has not been and is not being applied rigorously enough

First of all, it should be noted that the precautionary principle is not opposed to scientific research: on the contrary, its application calls for increased scientific research to confirm or deny risks. Furthermore, the idea of an “innovation principle” simply doesn’t make sense, firstly because innovation is a permanent feature of our economic system and culture, so it doesn’t need to be defended, and secondly, it can in no way be considered a value in itself. Finally, the precautionary principle is in no way intended to prohibit innovation, but rather to provide a scientific framework for it.

Unfortunately, this framework is still largely inadequate. The erosion of biodiversity in our regions is primarily due to the spread of pesticides, including neonicotinoids. 51 . Climate change is not under control, as shown by the IPCC’s sixth report, or UNEP’s 2023 report on the gap between needs and prospects for reducing greenhouse gas emissions. The major risks posed by synthetic biology 52 the origin and scope of which are well explained by Nicolas Bouleau in his book What Nature Knows (PUF, 2021), should clearly be the subject of the application of this principle, all the more so as the benefits of the experiments carried out are unclear.

This lack of real consideration for the precautionary principle is partly due to the power of lobbying by players who profit from maintaining the system as it is. Over the last few decades, scientific studies have shown how certain companies have succeeded in hijacking scientific research to create doubts about the causal links between their products and their effects on health and the environment. The book The Merchants of Doubt by Erik M. Conway and Naomi Oreskes shed light on these practices, developed by the tobacco industry and subsequently used in other cases, such as the ozone hole or climate change.

Merchants of doubt

In this book, historians of science Naomi Oreskes and Erik Conway give a well-documented account of their research into the “doubt factory”. They establish a link between the techniques invented by the tobacco industry in the 1960s-70s and those used by lobbies with an interest in minimizing ecological or health risks (acid rain, ozone, DDT, global warming…). Their strategy is not so much to counter scientific findings as to sow doubt about these findings and confusion about the reality of the threats, in order to delay the establishment of a public consensus as long as possible. All means are used: discrediting (or even harassing, threatening) scientists, using opportunistic or naive scientists or experts to conduct contradictory, partial (or even false) studies, or highlighting other potential causes for the risks or damage incurred. Their work, and that of other scientists, has given rise to a new scientific discipline, agnotology, the study of the cultural production of ignorance and doubt.

This strategy was also applied in the case of the sudden disappearance of bees, where pesticide producers diverted attention from their products to suggest that these disappearances were multi-factorial (varroa mites, Asian hornets, etc.). The book Pesticides, by François Dedieu (Seuil, 2022), a sociologist at Inrae, shows the extent of our ignorance about the effects of pesticides, and one of its causes: the administrative control authorities are overwhelmed by the number of products and molecules to be controlled. “Between 2008 and 2013, 2891 different commercial specialties of sanitary products were sold in France”. Against this backdrop, common sense would suggest a significant reduction in the marketing of pesticides.

In conclusion, not only does the precautionary principle have its place now more than ever, but substantial measures need to be taken in the way scientific activity operates, as recommended by the scientific council of the Fondation pour la Nature et l’Homme. 53 in its book Quelles sciences pour un monde à venir .

Tax is a major obstacle to business transfers in France

Company shares can have a high monetary value.

For listed companies, capital gains tax, inheritance tax and wealth tax do not pose any specific control issues. On the other hand, in the case of family businesses, taxation can jeopardize control of the company and, where applicable, the autonomy of its management. Indeed, if the succession has not been prepared for when the manager dies 54 if the succession has not been prepared, the heirs have to pay taxes (mainly inheritance tax and, where applicable, wealth tax) which may encourage them to sell their shares to pay these taxes, leading to a loss of family control. In this case, the company may be sold in whole or in part to a multinational or to an investment fund. 55

In France, inheritance tax has mainly been dealt with by the Dutreil pact pact, which was introduced in 1999 and has evolved several times since. Under certain conditions, this scheme enables heirs to pass on their inheritance tax to their heirs earlier than would otherwise be the case. As for the Wealth Tax (ISF), it has been replaced in France by the Real Estate Wealth Tax(IFI), which applies only to real estate assets and no longer to securities (thus excluding, in particular, shares in the capital of a company).

Two questions need to be answered:

  1. Are family businesses more successful, sustainable and responsible than others?

In the working paper Faut-il favoriser la transmission d’entreprise à la famille ou aux salariés? published in 2013 by the Direction Générale du Trésor, the authors point out that “empirical studies identifying management succession conclude that hereditary management is not accompanied by an increase in the profitability and sustainability of companies”. As for the question of ecological and social impact, we saw in Essentiel 6.3 that family businesses can be fearsomely predatory.

2 Is taxation a real obstacle to their development and sustainability?

According to the above-mentioned DGT document: “The taxation of business transfers “no longer appears to be a brake on business transfers” according to the Conseil des Prélèvements Obligatoires (2009), which estimates that the tax friction of a well-prepared family transfer is now limited to less than 5% of the value of the business, and can even become virtually nil at the price of elaborate strategies requiring the intervention of specialists.”

Since the transformation of the ISF into the IFI and the creation of sustainability funds, this conclusion can only be reinforced.

The “Start-up Nation” would be an ideal for the national economy.

In 2017, French President Emmanuel Macron launched the idea of the “Start-up nation” and made it a political mantra, extolling his government’s desire to foster the emergence of innovative companies, particularly in the field of new technologies, in order to contribute to the country’s economic development.

The expression comes from a book published in 2009 56 which attempts to explain the success of Israel’s technology companies. This political discourse also extols the idea that it would be desirable for France to produce a large number of “unicorns” (i.e. startups valued at over $1 billion and not listed on the stock market).

This approach is dangerous for several reasons.

  1. It leads young people to confuse start-ups with companies. According to BPI France, “literally meaning ‘company just starting out’, a startup is linked to the notion of experimenting with a new activity in an emerging market, where the risks are difficult to assess”. It is characterized by three conditions: “the prospect of strong growth, the use of a new technology and a significant need for financing”. The vast majority of companies are therefore not start-ups.
  2. It makes technology, and digital technology in particular, an important, if not central, purpose of entrepreneurial activity, when in fact it is marginal in terms of the number of businesses and jobs.
  3. It’s pushing to accelerate the “platformization” (or “uberization”) of the economy, which we can’t dream of either ecologically or socially.
  4. It leads us to believe that “raising a lot of money” and achieving a billion-dollar valuation is an ideal. Indeed, the criterion of raising funds is placed very high in the rhetoric about the success or otherwise of startups, as evidenced, for example, by reading the various barometers of economic and social performance produced by the France Digitale association. This ideal is harmful for several reasons. Firstly, in economic terms, raising funds does not mean making a profit: according to France Digitale’s 2022 barometer, barely a quarter of startups had achieved profitability (measured by positive EBITDA 57 ) by 2021. Secondly, there are very few “unicorns”: of the 1,300 startups listed by France Digitale in 2023, only a few dozen are “unicorns” (there are several hundred in the United States, the country with the most “unicorns”). 58 . Finally, this ideal has no ethical, economic, ecological or social basis. From a social point of view, it is very difficult to become a unicorn without human breakage; management has to be riveted on its financial objective and must not be bothered by states of mind or excessive social constraints.
  5. The priority in ecological and social terms is not to launch start-ups or “unicorns”, but to transform companies so that their business model becomes sober, low-carbon and biodiversity-friendly. There’s a lot of innovation to be done, a lot of initiatives to be led to get there, and a lot of money to be invested.
  6. On the technological front, the priority is clearly to reinforce the strategic autonomy of France and Europe, which have managed to achieve the feat of being dependent on China and/or the United States for bothhardware andsoftware. 59 . These serious errors are due to the application of a free-trade doctrine and a false and dangerous conception of competition. We won’t get out of them by relying on “unicorns”, but by rebuilding an industrial policy, and thus creating a framework for the development of relevant and possibly ambitious private initiatives.

Bosses are guided solely by money and power

In many speeches, company directors – most often those of large corporations – are portrayed as detestable characters. Extremely wealthy and well-paid, they are accused of running their companies for their own benefit (enrichment, prestige, whim, power), regardless of the social or environmental consequences, or the inhumanity of their management. This negative image of bosses is fuelled by the scandals and outrages of a few iconic bosses, by the regular media coverage of their incomes (especially when set against redundancy plans) and the real power of influence they have over society. 60

While this discourse is not without foundation, particularly at the top of the social ladder, we must be wary of any Manicheanism; “bosses” come in all shapes and sizes, and the exercise of power in the workplace, as elsewhere, particularly exposes those who exercise it to behavioral excesses.

Leadership and obscure personality traits

Numerous studies in psychology have shown important connections between obscure personality traits (see box) and leadership position. In an article published in 2021 61 researchers explored the relationship between the “dark triad” and leadership level. According to their findings, people with strong leadership display higher black triad scores, whether via self-evaluations or those carried out by subordinates.

Dark personality traits – dark triad, dark factor

Over the past twenty years, a great deal of psychological research has focused on identifying and studying “obscure” personality traits, i.e. those linked to ethically, morally or socially harmful behavior.

One of the most popular concepts is the “dark triad”. 62 three particularly destructive personality traits (narcissism, psychopathy and Machiavellianism) that are often concomitant.

In 2018, based on four studies of over 2,500 people, three researchers proposed a unifying theoretical framework, specifying the common denominator of the nine most-studied dark traits.63

This common core, which they call the “dark factor”, is defined as the “tendency [of an individual] to maximize his or her own utility – by ignoring, accepting or maliciously causing disutility in others – accompanied by beliefs that act as justifications” for this behavior.

Note that this description comes close to the characteristics of the central figure of the most widespread economic theories: homo economicus, a rational agent guided by the objective of maximizing his utility under constraint.

Source Visit the Dark factor website; Take the Dark factor test online

These results are hardly surprising. In an environment characterized by economic warfare and the quest for ever more, it’s not surprising that certain negative personality traits dominate among those who reach the highest spheres of power.

This is what Holt and his co-authors note, for example, in an article published in 2017: “In recent decades, ‘leadership’ has often been equated with outrageous or exaggerated (even psychopathic) behavior. This can be attributed to the fact that these figureheads are generally expected to be highly self-assured, even narcissistic individuals, often displaying a range of telltale traits, such as preoccupation with grandeur, exhibitionism, egocentricity and lack of empathy […] Many researchers […] have even postulated that psychopaths do very well in the business world because the environment seems to invite exactly the characteristics that these individuals possess.” 64

On the other hand, exercising power over others can also exacerbate “negative” tendencies (manipulation, desire to subjugate others, harassment, sexual abuse). As for the possession of money, linked to power (not always direct, it can be the power of influence, like that of footballers and stars), it can also negatively transform our relationship with others. Psychologists have shown that wealth, especially great wealth, increases social distance and reduces empathy. 65

Finally, it’s worth noting that when it comes to imagining leadership, the figure of the dominant leader – visionary, decisive, self-confident or even fear-inspiring – is still very present in society. This is one of the conclusions of a study published in 2023 by the Heart Leadership University association and Eranos, on the imaginations of leadership among young French people. 66 . Respondents to the questionnaire carried out for this study 67 were asked to choose from among six photographs of personalities 68 that best represented leardership as they would like it to be today. Elon Musk and Mark Zuckerberg together garnered almost a quarter of the votes (15% and 8% respectively), showing that the image of the big boss who made his fortune in fields considered avant-garde is still very much alive, despite the scandals surrounding these two personalities.

Avoid a Manichean vision

The negative image of big business is reflected in the positions taken by political and trade union leaders, in films and news reports, and in the entire business community, even though this milieu is highly heterogeneous in human terms.

There’s no comparison between Elon Musk or Bernard Arnault and the boss of an SME, in terms of power, remuneration and wealth; of course, there are “human” bosses in many companies.

The boss has a specific role that’s hard to deny: that of conductor and referee. This role implies taking decisions that may not be to the liking of part of the company’s workforce (whatever the personality of the manager).

Even with the best of intentions, running a business is a perilous exercise in which you have to reconcile :

  • the necessary search for profitability (without which the company will eventually disappear);
  • taking into account external constraints (regulatory, economic, competitive, often marked by a tendency towards social and environmental undercutting);
  • perception and anticipation of major current and future developments (technological, societal, environmental);
  • the art of leading others with consideration (employees also being human beings and therefore not angels by definition, but not servile beings either);
  • or even respect for the company’s mission and values (where these exist).

This often requires personal work as well as “technical” and emotional training. This is what the Heart Leadership University association offers, for example. 69 with its Heart to Action program, in which business leaders become aware of, and exercise, their “intelligence of the heart” (IDC) in order to transform their company, taking into account the major challenges of the 21st century.

In his research work, HLU showed that CDI could indeed be taught (much more through practice than theory), and that the resulting personal transformation of the manager led to an effective transformation of the company. 70 . These studies have also shown that such an approach is complex and difficult, as there are many obstacles to overcome: obstacles internal to the manager (in particular certain fears), obstacles specific to the organization (its type of governance and its rigidities, the culture and the common standard of thinking, resistance from employees), and finally external obstacles (conjunctural or more structural relating to the vision of a company’s role).

What is intelligence of the heart (IDC)?

The intelligence of the heart makes it possible to decide and manage a company without limiting oneself to the objective of economic performance and a rational approach based on logic and figures. It is cultivated around three fundamentals: trusting one’s intuition to perceive the world ahead and innovate differently; having the courage to be oneself, to assume one’s values and act accordingly; and developing empathy by learning to better connect with others and one’s environment, in order to create products and services that are useful to the world, while “encapacitating” employees. Above all, the intelligence of the heart lies in the combination of these three skills. This is particularly true of courage, without which neither intuition nor empathy could be expressed.

Find out more: see the research carried out by Heart Leadership University 69

Behind the condemnation of “bosses” may lie the idea that horizontal governance structures, or even self-management, would be preferable to “vertical”, highly hierarchical models, often associated with the existence of a “boss”.

However, the situation is not so Manichean.

Let’s start by recalling that the company is a place of commitments and contracts (with customers, suppliers, employees, public bodies and investors). Keeping these commitments means defining responsibilities and making decisions. That’s why it’s important for managers to clarify governance (who decides what and how?) and to ensure that employees are constantly involved in decision-making at the right level.

Secondly, as we saw inEssentiel 4 on the challenges and variety of forms of governance, it is possible to institute more democratic modes of governance than that of the traditional hierarchical company, so that power is “shared”, not just according to the rate of capital ownership, but also according to rules defining the link between involvement, contribution in/to the company and participation in decision-making.